The Paradox of Openness Appropriability and the Use of External Sources of Knowledge for Innovation

To innovate, firms often need to draw from a wide number of different sources of knowledge from outside their organization. At the same time as firms need to be open to external sources, they also need to be focused on capturing returns to their innovative ideas. This gives rise to a paradox of openness the creation of innovations often requires openness and commercialization of innovations requires appropriability. Using an econometric analysis of the UK innovation survey, we find the openness of firms to external sources of innovation is curvilinearly (taking an inverted U-shape) related to the strength of the firm’s appropriability strategy. We also find that the greater the presences of the absorptive capacity within a firm, the greater are the chances that it will be open to external sources. We explore the implications of these findings for theory and empirical research.

[1]  R. Veugelers,et al.  R&D Cooperation and Spillovers: Some Empirical Evidence , 1998 .

[2]  Herbert A. Simon,et al.  Administrative behavior; a study of decision making processes in administrative Organization : with a new introduction / Hebert A. simon , 1947 .

[3]  J. Gans,et al.  The Product Market and the Market for 'Ideas': Commercialization Strategies for Technology Entrepreneurs , 2002 .

[4]  A. Arora,et al.  Markets for Technology: The Economics of Innovation and Corporate Strategy , 2002 .

[5]  Kathleen M. Eisenhardt,et al.  DYNAMIC CAPABILITIES, WHAT ARE THEY? , 2000 .

[6]  Keith Pavitt,et al.  Technological Accumulation, Diversification and Organisation in UK Companies, 1945-1983 , 1989 .

[7]  S. Zahra,et al.  Sources of capabilities, integration and technology commercialization , 2002 .

[8]  A. Arora PATENTS, LICENSING, AND MARKET STRUCTURE IN THE CHEMICAL INDUSTRY , 1996 .

[9]  J. Brown,et al.  Bridging epistemologies: The generative dance between organizational knowledge and organizational knowing , 1999, STUDI ORGANIZZATIVI.

[10]  Keith Pavitt,et al.  The Size Distribution of Innovating Firms in the UK: 1945-1983 , 1987 .

[11]  J. Pennings,et al.  Internal capabilities, external networks, and performance: a study on technology‐based ventures , 2001 .

[12]  S. Shane A General Theory of Entrepreneurship: The Individual-Opportunity Nexus , 2003 .

[13]  L. Jeppesen User Toolkits for Innovation: Consumers Support Each Other , 2005 .

[14]  D. Teece Profiting from technological innovation: Implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy , 1993 .

[15]  Sydney Gregory Inside the black box: technology and economics: Rosenberg, N Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK (1982) 304pp , 1985 .

[16]  Keith Pavitt,et al.  USES AND ABUSES OF PATENT STATISTICS , 1988 .

[17]  Kim B. Clark,et al.  Architectural Innovation: The Reconfiguration of Existing Product Technologies and the Failure of , 1990 .

[18]  Daniel A. Levinthal,et al.  Innovation and Learning: The Two Faces of R&D , 1989 .

[19]  Daniel A. Levinthal,et al.  ABSORPTIVE CAPACITY: A NEW PERSPECTIVE ON LEARNING AND INNOVATION , 1990 .

[20]  W. Ocasio TOWARDS AN ATTENTION-BASED VIEW OF THE FIRM , 1997 .

[21]  Jennifer W. Spencer,et al.  How Relevant is University-Based Scientific Research to Private High-Technology Firms? A United States–Japan Comparison , 2001 .

[22]  Henry Chesbrough,et al.  When is Virtual Virtuous? Organizing for Innovation , 1999 .

[23]  Joel A. C. Baum,et al.  Don't go it alone: alliance network composition and startups' performance in Canadian biotechnology , 2000 .

[24]  D. Mowery,et al.  Strategic alliances and interfirm knowledge transfer , 1996 .

[25]  N. Rosenberg Why do firms do basic research (with their own money) , 1990 .

[26]  Dennis A. Rondinelli,et al.  National innovation systems: A comparative analysis , 1993 .

[27]  Ulrich Kaiser An empirical test of models explaining research expenditures and research cooperation: evidence for the German service sector , 2002 .

[28]  Thomas S. Ulen An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. By Richard R. Nelson and Sidney G. Winter. (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1982. xi + 437 pp. $25.00.) , 1983, Business History Review.

[29]  J. Schumpeter,et al.  Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy , 1943 .

[30]  S. Winter,et al.  Appropriating the Returns from Industrial Research and Development , 1987 .

[31]  Richard R. Nelson,et al.  On the Sources and Significance of Interindustry Differences in Technological Opportunities , 1995 .

[32]  Stefano Brusoni,et al.  Knowledge Specialisation and the Boundaries of the Firm: Why Do Firms Know More Than They Do? , 2001 .

[33]  Mark Harvey,et al.  Analysing distributed processes of provision and innovation , 2003 .

[34]  A. Salter,et al.  My Precious. The Role of Appropriability Strategies in Shaping Innovative Performance , 2005 .

[35]  Gary P. Pisano,et al.  The Development Factory: Unlocking the Potential of Process Innovation , 1996 .

[36]  Daniel A. Levinthal,et al.  The myopia of learning , 1993 .

[37]  John Cullen,et al.  Democratizing Innovation , 2020, Encyclopedia of Creativity, Invention, Innovation and Entrepreneurship.

[38]  David Neil Managing innovation: integrating technological, market and organisational change. (Book Reviews) , 2002 .

[39]  Peter J. Lane,et al.  Relative absorptive capacity and interorganizational learning , 1998 .

[40]  Joel A. C. Baum,et al.  Institutional Linkages and Organizational Mortality , 1991 .

[41]  A. Salter,et al.  Open for innovation: the role of openness in explaining innovation performance among U.K. manufacturing firms , 2006 .

[42]  S. Zahra,et al.  Absorptive Capacity: A Review, Reconceptualization, and Extension , 2002 .

[43]  Jacques Mairesse,et al.  Accounting for Innovation and Measuring Innovativeness: An Illustrative Framework and an Application , 2002 .

[44]  K. Arrow Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention , 1962 .