Oil Price Shocks and the U.S. Stagflation of the 1970s: Some Insights from GEM

Using a variant of the IMF's Global Economy Model (GEM), featuring energy as both an intermediate input into production and a final consumption good, this paper examines the macroeconomic implications of large increases in the price of energy. Within a fully optimizing framework with nominal and real rigidities arising from costly adjustment, large increases in energy prices can generate inflation persistence similar to that seen in the 1970s if the monetary authority misperceives the economyOs supply capacity and workers are able to temporarily resist some of the erosion in their real consumption wages resulting from the energy price increase. In the absence of these two responses, the model suggests that energy price shocks cannot generate the type of stagflation witnessed in the 1970s. The analysis goes some way toward reconciling the results found in the empirical literature on the changing nature of the macroeconomic implications of oil price shocks.

[1]  John B. Taylor Discretion versus policy rules in practice , 1993 .

[2]  Richard Black,et al.  A Robust Method For Simulating Forward-Looking Models , 1998 .

[3]  Alan S. Blinder,et al.  Economic policy and the great stagflation , 1979 .

[4]  Knut Anton Mork,et al.  Oil and the Macroeconomy When Prices Go Up and Down: An Extension of Hamilton's Results , 1989, Journal of Political Economy.

[5]  L. Kilian The Effects of Exogenous Oil Supply Shocks on Output and Inflation: Evidence from the G7 Countries , 2005 .

[6]  M. Watson,et al.  Systematic Monetary Policy and the Effects of Oil Price Shocks , 1997 .

[7]  D. B. Cashion A Perspective on Inflation Targeting , 2004 .

[8]  In-Moo Kim,et al.  The role of energy in real business cycle models , 1992 .

[9]  Athanasios Orphanides Historical monetary policy analysis and the Taylor rule , 2003 .

[10]  A. Atkeson,et al.  Putty-clay capital and energy , 1995 .

[11]  Michel Juillard,et al.  An algorithm competition: First-order iterations versus Newton-based techniques , 1998 .

[12]  The U.S. Dollar and the Trade Deficit: What Accounts for the Late 1990s? , 2003, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[13]  F. Smets,et al.  An estimated dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model of the euro area. NBB Working Paper Nr. 35 , 2002 .

[14]  M. Hooker,et al.  What happened to the oil price-macroeconomy relationship? , 1996 .

[15]  Douglas Laxton,et al.  The Macroeconomic Effects of Higher Oil Prices , 2002, National Institute Economic Review.

[16]  Athanasios Orphanides Activist Stabilization Policy and Inflation: The Taylor Rule in the 1970s , 2000 .

[17]  Mario J. Crucini,et al.  Oil Prices and the Terms of Trade , 1998 .

[18]  J. Sachs,et al.  Economics of worldwide stagflation , 1986 .

[19]  B. Hunt Oil Price Shocks: Can They Account for the Stagflation in the 1970s? , 2005, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[20]  R. Tetlow,et al.  A Simple Multivariate Filter for the Measurement of Potential Output , 1992 .

[21]  M. Hooker Are Oil Shocks Inflationary?: Asymmetric and Nonlinear Specifications versus Changes in Regime , 1999 .

[22]  James D. Hamilton Oil and the Macroeconomy since World War II , 1983, Journal of Political Economy.

[23]  G. Calvo Staggered prices in a utility-maximizing framework , 1983 .

[24]  James D. Hamilton What is an Oil Shock? , 2000 .

[25]  R. Hall,et al.  Energy Prices, Inflation, and Recession, 1974-1975 , 1979 .