Does a Store Brand Always Hurt the Manufacturer of a Competing National Brand?

It is generally believed that store brands hurt the manufacturers of competing national brands while benefiting retailers. In this study, we challenge this notion by studying the impacts of a store brand when it is introduced by a power retailer. We show that a store brand may benefit the manufacturer when the interaction between the manufacturer and retailer is modeled as a retailer-led Stackelberg game. This phenomenon occurs because the store brand changes the nature of the strategic interaction between the manufacturer and retailer in our model. In particular, while the interaction is always vertical strategic substitutability without a store brand, it may become vertical strategic independence with one. With the store brand, the demand for the national brand becomes larger, and the wholesale price for the national brand may increase, both of which benefit the manufacturer. Finally, the store brand may lessen the double marginalization problem of the supply chain for the national brand in the retailer-led Stackelberg game, but does so in an unconventional way: The reduction in the double marginalization effect may come from a lowered retail markup instead of a lowered wholesale price. Our results reconcile some discrepancies between theoretical predictions and empirical findings regarding the impacts of store brands on manufacturers.

[1]  Stephen M. Gilbert,et al.  Private Labels: Facilitators or Impediments to Supply Chain Coordination , 2011, Decis. Sci..

[2]  J. M. Villas-Boas,et al.  Retailer, Manufacturers, and Individual Consumers: Modeling the Supply Side in the Ketchup Marketplace , 2005 .

[3]  Hon-Shiang Lau,et al.  Dollar vs. percentage markup pricing schemes under a dominant retailer , 2013, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[4]  P. Rey,et al.  Buyer Power and Intrabrand Coordination , 2011 .

[5]  Leslie M. Marx,et al.  Upfront payments and exclusion in downstream markets , 2008 .

[6]  P. Seetharaman,et al.  Bounded Rationality in Pricing under State-Dependent Demand: Do Firms Look Ahead, and if So, How Far? , 2007 .

[7]  Raj Sethuraman,et al.  Assessing the External Validity of Analytical Results from National Brand and Store Brand Competition Models , 2009, Mark. Sci..

[8]  G. Zaccour,et al.  Could co-op advertising be a manufacturer's counterstrategy to store brands? , 2006 .

[9]  Hans Sebastian Heese,et al.  Supply chain interactions due to store-brand introductions: The impact of retail competition , 2010, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[10]  David E. Mills Why Retailers Sell Private Labels , 1995 .

[11]  Hans Sebastian Heese,et al.  Competing with channel partners: Supply chain conflict when retailers introduce store brands , 2010 .

[12]  S. C. Choi,et al.  Price competition in a duopoly common retailer channel , 1996 .

[13]  Ronald W. Cotterill,et al.  Market Share and Price Setting Behavior for Private Labels and National Brands , 2000 .

[14]  T. Gabrielsen,et al.  Private Labels, Price Rivalry, and Public Policy ¤ , 2000 .

[15]  Philippe Bontems,et al.  Strategic Effects of Private Labels , 1999 .

[16]  S. C. Choi,et al.  Price Competition in a Channel Structure with a Common Retailer , 1991 .

[17]  Marnik G. Dekimpe,et al.  The increasing power of store brands: Building loyalty and market share , 1997 .

[18]  Ira Horowitz,et al.  An option-pricing look at the introduction of private labels , 2000, J. Oper. Res. Soc..

[19]  Scott A. Neslin,et al.  Pursuing the Value-Conscious Consumer: Store Brands versus National Brand Promotions , 2001 .

[20]  Pradeep K. Chintagunta,et al.  Manufacturer-Retailer Channel Interactions and Implications for Channel Power: An Empirical Investigation of Pricing in a Local Market , 2000 .

[21]  K. Sudhir,et al.  Structural Analysis of Manufacturer Pricing in the Presence of a Strategic Retailer , 2001 .

[22]  Jagmohan S. Raju,et al.  How category characteristics affect the number of store brands offered by the retailer: a model and empirical analysis , 2004 .

[23]  Stephen J. Hoch,et al.  Why Store Brand Penetration Varies by Retailer , 1997 .

[24]  R. Staelin,et al.  Vertical Strategic Interaction: Implications for Channel Pricing Strategy , 1997 .

[25]  Hans Sebastian Heese,et al.  Supply Chain Conflict Due to Store Brands: The Value of Wholesale Price Commitment in a Retail Supply Chain , 2010, Decis. Sci..

[26]  Tülin Erdem,et al.  Performance of Store Brands: A Cross-Country Analysis of Consumer Store-Brand Preferences, Perceptions, and Risk , 2004 .

[27]  Jayashankar M. Swaminathan,et al.  Product Line Design with Component Commonality and Cost-Reduction Effort , 2006, Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag..

[28]  Pradeep Chintagunta,et al.  Investigating the Effects of Store-Brand Introduction on Retailer Demand and Pricing Behavior , 2002, Manag. Sci..

[29]  Georges Zaccour,et al.  Stackelberg Leadership in a Marketing Channel , 2001, IGTR.

[30]  Trichy V. Krishnan,et al.  Guaranteed profit margins : A demonstration of retailer power , 1997 .

[31]  David E. Mills Private labels and manufacturer counterstrategies , 1999 .

[32]  R. Lal,et al.  Building Store Loyalty through Store Brands , 2000 .

[33]  Prasad A. Naik,et al.  The effects of expert quality evaluations versus brand name on price premiums , 2003 .

[34]  K. Moorthy,et al.  Product and Price Competition in a Duopoly , 1988 .

[35]  Anne T. Coughlan,et al.  Private label positioning: Quality versus feature differentiation from the national brand , 2006 .

[36]  Jagmohan S. Raju,et al.  The introduction and performance of store brands , 1995 .

[37]  Pradeep K. Chintagunta,et al.  Store Brands: Who Buys Them and What Happens to Retail Prices When They Are Introduced? , 2004 .

[38]  Ronald T. Wilcox,et al.  Private-Labels and the Channel Relationship: A Cross-Category Analysis , 1998 .

[39]  Jagmohan S. Raju,et al.  Positioning of Store Brands , 2002 .

[40]  Hean Tat Keh,et al.  Modelling hybrid distribution channels: a game-theoretic analysis , 2003 .

[41]  Anthony J. Dukes,et al.  Strategic Assortment Reduction by a Dominant Retailer , 2009, Mark. Sci..

[42]  Chi-Cheng Wu,et al.  A Positive Theory of Private Label: A Strategic Role of Private Label in a Duopoly National-Brand Market , 2005 .

[43]  Koen Pauwels,et al.  Who Benefits from Store Brand Entry , 2004 .

[44]  E. Nijssen,et al.  Strategic reactions of national brand manufacturers towards private labels: An empirical study in The Netherlands , 2002 .

[45]  Srinagesh Gavirneni,et al.  Supply chains in the presence of store brands , 2013, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[46]  Jun Zhang,et al.  Impacts of Power Structure on Supply Chains with Uncertain Demand , 2013 .

[47]  Bin Liu,et al.  Pricing decisions in a dual channels system with different power structures , 2011, ICSSSM11.

[48]  Stephen J. Hoch,et al.  How Should National Brands Think about Private Labels , 1996 .

[49]  Florian Zettelmeyer,et al.  The Strategic Positioning of Store Brands in Retailer–Manufacturer Negotiations , 2004 .

[50]  Kusum L. Ailawadi,et al.  An Empirical Analysis of the Determinants of Retail Margins: The Role of Store-Brand Share , 2004 .

[51]  Gérard P. Cachon,et al.  Supply Chain Coordination with Revenue-Sharing Contracts: Strengths and Limitations , 2005, Manag. Sci..

[52]  Zuo-Jun Max Shen,et al.  Channel Performance Under Consignment Contract with Revenue Sharing , 2004, Manag. Sci..