Globalization, Markups, and US Welfare

This paper estimates the impact of globalization on markups, and the effect of changing markups on US welfare, in a monopolistic competition model. We work with symmetric translog preferences, which allow for endogenous markups and firm entry and exit, thereby changing product variety. We find that between 1992 and 2005, US import shares rose and US firms exited, leading to an implied fall in markups, while variety went up because of imports. US welfare rose by nearly 1 percent as a result of these changes, with product variety contributing one-half of that total and declining markups the other half.

[1]  Benjamin Faber,et al.  Retail Globalization and Household Welfare: Evidence from Mexico , 2015, Journal of Political Economy.

[2]  Kerryn Cox The Effects of Trade Reform on Labour Mobility Across South African Local Labour Markets , 2018 .

[3]  Costas Arkolakis,et al.  The Elusive Pro-Competitive Effects of Trade , 2015 .

[4]  Jeffrey R. Campbell,et al.  Understanding Markups in the Open Economy , 2015 .

[5]  Anson Soderbery Estimating import supply and demand elasticities : Analysis and implications ☆ , 2015 .

[6]  R. Feenstra Restoring the Product Variety and Pro-Competitive Gains from Trade with Heterogeneous Firms and Bounded Productivity , 2014 .

[7]  Pablo D. Fajgelbaum,et al.  Measuring the Unequal Gains from Trade , 2014 .

[8]  C. Edmond,et al.  credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Competition, Markups, and the Gains from International Trade , 2012 .

[9]  Jan De Loecker,et al.  Prices, Markups and Trade Reform , 2012 .

[10]  Florin O. Bilbiie,et al.  Endogenous Entry, Product Variety, and Business Cycles , 2007, Journal of Political Economy.

[11]  J. Rodrı́guez-López Prices and Exchange Rates: A Theory of Disconnect , 2011 .

[12]  Anson Soderbery Investigating the asymptotic properties of import elasticity estimates , 2010 .

[13]  Ina Simonovska Income Differences and Prices of Tradables , 2010 .

[14]  R. Feenstra,et al.  Effects of Terms of Trade Gains and Tariff Changes on the Measurement of U.S. Productivity Growth , 2009 .

[15]  Costas Arkolakis,et al.  New Trade Models, Same Old Gains? , 2009 .

[16]  Bruce A. Blonigen,et al.  Measuring the Benefits of Product Variety with an Accurate Variety Set , 2009 .

[17]  Anson Soderbery Investigating the Asymptotic Properties of Elasticity of Substitution Estimates: A Monte Carlo Study of Feenstra (1994) , 2009 .

[18]  K. Behrens,et al.  Trade, Wages, and Productivity , 2012 .

[19]  H. Badinger,et al.  Trade policy and productivity , 2008 .

[20]  H. Badinger,et al.  Market size, trade, competition and productivity: evidence from OECD manufacturing industries , 2007 .

[21]  Kristian Behrens,et al.  General equilibrium models of monopolistic competition: A new approach , 2007, J. Econ. Theory.

[22]  H. Badinger,et al.  Has the EU's Single Market Program Fostered Competition? Testing for a Decrease in Mark-Up Ratios in EU Industries , 2007 .

[23]  Peter K. Schott,et al.  Multi-Product Firms and Trade Liberalization , 2006 .

[24]  P. Allanson,et al.  Multiproduct Firms and Market Structure: An Explorative Application to the Product Life Cycle , 2005 .

[25]  G. Ottaviano,et al.  Market Size, Trade, and Productivity , 2005, World Scientific Studies in International Economics.

[26]  J. Konings,et al.  The Effects of Privatization and Competitive Pressure on Firms' Price-Cost Margins: Micro Evidence from Emerging Economies , 2005, Review of Economics and Statistics.

[27]  H. Vandenbussche,et al.  Antidumping protection and markups of domestic firms , 2005 .

[28]  David E. Weinstein,et al.  Globalization and the Gains from Variety , 2004 .

[29]  Onathan,et al.  Plants and Productivity in International Trade , 2004 .

[30]  Roberto Rigobon,et al.  Identification Through Heteroskedasticity , 2003, Review of Economics and Statistics.

[31]  A. Bottasso,et al.  Market power, productivity and the EU Single Market Program: Evidence from a panel of Italian firms , 2001 .

[32]  K. Head,et al.  Increasing Returns versus National Product Differentiation as an Explanation for the Pattern of US-C , 2001 .

[33]  Euysung Kim Trade liberalization and productivity growth in Korean manufacturing industries: price protection, market power, and scale efficiency , 2000 .

[34]  K. Head,et al.  Rationalization effects of tariff reductions , 1999 .

[35]  Pravin Krishna,et al.  Trade liberalization, market discipline and productivity growth: new evidence from India , 1998 .

[36]  J. Tybout,et al.  Trade liberalization and the dimensions of efficiency change in Mexican manufacturing industries , 1995 .

[37]  R. Feenstra,et al.  Bias in U.S. Import Prices and Demand , 1994 .

[38]  A. Harrison Productivity, imperfect competition and trade reform: Theory and evidence , 1994 .

[39]  Steven T. Berry Estimating Discrete-Choice Models of Product Differentiation , 1994 .

[40]  R. Feenstra New Product Varieties and the Measurement of International Prices , 1994 .

[41]  J. Levinsohn Testing the Imports-as-Market-Discipline Hypothesis , 1991 .

[42]  J. Melo,et al.  The effects of trade reforms on scale and technical efficiency: New evidence from Chile , 1991 .

[43]  J. Bergstrand The Generalized Gravity Equation, Monopolistic Competition, and the Factor-Proportions Theory in International Trade , 1989 .

[44]  Timothy F. Bresnahan,et al.  Empirical studies of industries with market power , 1989 .

[45]  Ian Domowitz,et al.  Market Structure and Cyclical Fluctuations in U.S. Manufacturing , 1986 .

[46]  P. Krugman Increasing returns, monopolistic competition, and international trade , 1979 .

[47]  Walter Diewert,et al.  Exact and superlative index numbers , 1976 .

[48]  D. Jorgenson,et al.  Transcendental Logarithmic Utility Functions , 1975 .

[49]  Jacob Viner,et al.  Studies in the Theory of International Trade. , 1937 .