Primaries and the New Hampshire Effect

Candidates for U.S. presidential elections are determined through sequential elections in single states, the primaries. We develop a model in which candidates can influence their winning probability in electoral districts by spending money on campaigning. The equilibrium replicates several stylized facts very well: Campaigning is very intensive in the first district. The outcome of the first election then creates an asymmetry in the candidates’ incentives to campaign in the next district, which endogenously increases the equilibrium probability that the first winner wins in further districts. On the normative side, our model oers a possible explanation for the sequential organization: It leads (in expectation) to a lower level of advertising expenditures than simultaneous elections. Moreover, if one of the candidates is the more eective campaigner, sequential elections also perform better with regard to the selection of the best candidate.

[1]  Steven Callander Bandwagons and Momentum in Sequential Voting , 2007 .

[2]  Balázs Szentes,et al.  Three-object two-bidder simultaneous auctions: chopsticks and tetrahedra , 2003, Games Econ. Behav..

[3]  E. Maskin,et al.  The Existence of Equilibrium in Discontinuous Economic Games, I: Theory , 1986 .

[4]  Dan Kovenock,et al.  The solution to the Tullock rent-seeking game when R>2: Mixed-strategy equilibria and mean dissipation rates , 1994 .

[5]  Tilman Klumpp,et al.  Early Round Upsets and Championship Blowouts , 2004 .

[6]  J. Witcover Marathon: The Pursuit of the Presidency 1972-1976 , 1977 .

[7]  Larry M. Bartels Presidential Primaries and the Dynamics of Public Choice , 1988 .

[8]  Rebecca B. Morton,et al.  Information Asymmetries and Simultaneous versus Sequential Voting , 1999, American Political Science Review.

[9]  Mandar P. Oak On the Role of the Primary System in Candidate Selection , 2006 .

[10]  Ian L. Gale,et al.  Caps on Political Lobbying , 1998 .

[11]  Dan Kovenock,et al.  Equilibrium and efficiency in the tug-of-war , 2019 .

[12]  O. Swank A comment on sequential elections and overlapping terms: voting for US Senate , 2001 .

[13]  G. Tullock Efficient Rent Seeking , 2001 .

[14]  James M. Snyder,et al.  Campaign Contributions as Investments: The U.S. House of Representatives, 1980-1986 , 1990, Journal of Political Economy.

[15]  Balázs Szentes,et al.  Beyond chopsticks: Symmetric equilibria in majority auction games , 2003, Games Econ. Behav..

[16]  Koleman Strumpf Strategic Competition in Sequential Election Contests , 2002 .

[17]  J. Snyder Election Goals and the Allocation of Campaign Resources , 1989 .

[18]  Michael R. Baye,et al.  The all-pay auction with complete information , 1990 .

[19]  Robert S. Erikson,et al.  Equilibria in Campaign Spending Games: Theory and Data , 2000, American Political Science Review.

[20]  S. Bikhchandani,et al.  You have printed the following article : A Theory of Fads , Fashion , Custom , and Cultural Change as Informational Cascades , 2007 .

[21]  Yeon-Koo Che,et al.  Difference-Form Contests and the Robustness of All-Pay Auctions , 2000, Games Econ. Behav..

[22]  Jac C. Heckelman Sequential elections and overlapping terms: voting for US Senate , 2000 .

[23]  Michele Piccione,et al.  Sequential Voting Procedures in Symmetric Binary Elections , 2000, Journal of Political Economy.

[24]  R. Tollison,et al.  Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society , 1982 .

[25]  M. J. Robinson,et al.  Over the wire and on TV , 1983 .

[26]  Stefan Szymanski,et al.  The Economic Design of Sporting Contests , 2003 .

[27]  Timothy B. Krebs,et al.  Media and Momentum , 2005 .

[28]  James Bernard Murphy,et al.  Tug of War. , 2003 .