Behavioral Heterogeneity Under Approval and Plurality Voting

Approval voting (AV) has been defended and criticized from many different viewpoints. In this paper, I will concentrate on two topics: preference intensities and strategic behavior. A voter is usually defined as voting sincerely under AV if he or she gives a vote to all candidates standing higher in his or her ranking than the lowest-ranking candidate for whom he or she gives a vote. There are no ‘holes’ in a voter’s approval set.1 Since this kind of behavior is extremely rare, it has been claimed that approval voting makes strategic voting unnecessary (Brams and Fishburn 1978). On the other hand, Niemi (1984) has argued (see also van Newenhizen and Saari 1988a,b), that even though strategic voting may be rare under AV, even incere voting may require a considerable amount of strategic thinking under this rule. If strategic voting is defined by the fact that a voter gives his or her vote to a candidate who is lower in his or her ranking than some candidate for whom he or she does not vote (see, e.g., Brams and Sanver 2006), I will be studying strategic behavior but not strategic voting under AV here.

[1]  R. Niemi The Problem of Strategic Behavior under Approval Voting , 1984, American Political Science Review.

[2]  S. Merrill,et al.  Strategic Voting in Multicandidate Elections under Uncertainty and under Risk , 1981 .

[3]  Aki Lehtinen The Welfare Consequences of Strategic Voting in Two Commonly Used Parliamentary Agendas , 2007 .

[4]  Aki Lehtinen,et al.  Signal extraction for simulated games with a large number of players , 2006, Comput. Stat. Data Anal..

[5]  Peter C. Fishburn,et al.  Going from theory to practice: the mixed success of approval voting , 2005, Soc. Choice Welf..

[6]  Keith Dowding,et al.  In Praise of Manipulation , 2007, British Journal of Political Science.

[7]  Miguel A. Ballester,et al.  Sincere Voting with Cardinal Preferences: Approval Voting , 2007 .

[8]  Jerry S. Kelly,et al.  Social Choice Theory: An Introduction , 1988 .

[9]  Samuel Merrill,et al.  Approval Voting: A ‘Best Buy’ Method for Multi-candidate Elections? , 1979 .

[10]  Cyril Carter,et al.  Admissible and sincere strategies under approval voting , 1990 .

[11]  Manfred J. Holler Power, Voting, and Voting Power , 2012 .

[12]  Steven J. Brams,et al.  Critical Strategies Under Approval Voting: Who Gets Ruled In And Ruled Out , 2006 .

[13]  Samuel Merrill,et al.  Strategic decisions under one-stage multi-candidate voting systems , 1981 .

[14]  J. Kelly Social Choice Theory: An Introduction , 1988 .

[15]  Joseph L. Bernd,et al.  Mathematical applications in political science , 1976 .

[16]  Douglas Muzzio,et al.  APPROVAL VOTING , 1983 .

[17]  L. Cranor,et al.  Declared-strategy voting: an instrument for group decision-making , 1996 .

[18]  Aki Lehtinen,et al.  The welfare consequences of strategic behaviour under approval and plurality voting , 2008 .

[19]  D. Saari,et al.  The problem of indeterminacy in approval, multiple, and truncated voting systems , 1988 .

[20]  Donald G. Saari,et al.  Is approval voting an ‘unmitigated evil’?: A response to Brams, Fishburn, and Merrill , 1987 .

[21]  Aki Lehtinen,et al.  The Borda rule is also intended for dishonest men , 2007 .

[22]  Donald G. Saari,et al.  Analyzing a nail-biting election , 2001, Soc. Choice Welf..

[23]  J. Muth Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements , 1961 .

[24]  Dale T. Hoffman,et al.  A MODEL FOR STRATEGIC VOTING , 1982 .