A theory of intermediated investment with hyperbolic discounting investors

Financial intermediaries may reduce welfare losses caused by hyperbolic discounting investors, who may liquidate their investment prematurely when the liquidation cost is low. In a competitive equilibrium, sophisticated investors are offered contracts with perfect commitment, and first best results are achieved; naive investors are attracted by contracts that offer seemingly attractive returns in the long run but introduce discontinuous penalties for early withdrawal. If the investor types are private information, naive investors withdraw early and cross-subsidize sophisticated investors. When a secondary market for long-term contracts opens for trading, financial intermediaries are compelled to offer contracts that have more flexible withdrawal options with linear schemes, and the welfare of naive investors is improved. Arbitrage-free linear contracts allow for a unique term structure for interest rates that includes a premium for naivete. Solvency requirements may limit competition for contracts and result in positive profits; banks that have capital are able to compete more aggressively, which improves investor welfare.

[1]  André Kurmann,et al.  News Shocks and the Slope of the Term Structure of Interest Rates , 2010 .

[2]  Paul Heidhues,et al.  Inferior Products and Profitable Deception , 2017 .

[3]  R. Brooks,et al.  Embedded Options in Enhanced Certificates of Deposit , 2004 .

[4]  Ulrike Malmendier,et al.  Contract Design and Self-Control: Theory and Evidence , 2004 .

[5]  Dean S. Karlan,et al.  A Review of Commitment Savings Products in Development Countries , 2003 .

[6]  Kim C. Border,et al.  Infinite Dimensional Analysis: A Hitchhiker’s Guide , 1994 .

[7]  D. Duffie,et al.  A YIELD-FACTOR MODEL OF INTEREST RATES , 1996 .

[8]  J. List,et al.  Evidence of Early Withdrawal in Time Deposit Portfolios , 1999 .

[9]  Nicolas Treich,et al.  Over-savings and hyperbolic discounting , 2006 .

[10]  David Laibson,et al.  Self Control and Liquidity: How to Design a Commitment Contract , 2011 .

[11]  R. Brooks Computing yields on enhanced CDs , 1996 .

[12]  Peter A. Diamond,et al.  Quasi-Hyperbolic Discounting and Retirement , 2000 .

[13]  Matthew Rabin,et al.  Optimal Sin Taxes , 2006 .

[14]  Matthew Rabin,et al.  Choice and Procrastination , 2000 .

[15]  A. Ambrus,et al.  Commitment-Flexibility Trade-Off and Withdrawal Penalties , 2012 .

[16]  David Laibson,et al.  Estimating Discount Functions with Consumption Choices Over the Lifecycle , 2007 .

[17]  Min Wei,et al.  What Does the Yield Curve Tell Us About GDP Growth? , 2003 .

[18]  T. Mulgan The Contract Theory , 2006 .

[19]  Banking, incentive constraints, and demand deposit contracts with nonlinear returns , 1996 .

[20]  G. Loewenstein,et al.  Time Discounting and Time Preference: A Critical Review , 2002 .

[21]  Karna Basu Hyperbolic Discounting and the Sustainability of Rotational Savings Arrangements , 2011 .

[22]  Allen N. Berger,et al.  The Rigidity of Prices: Evidence from the Banking Industry , 1991 .

[23]  J. Rochet,et al.  Microeconomics of banking , 1997 .

[24]  Arturo Estrella,et al.  The term structure as a predictor of real economic activity , 1991 .

[25]  David I. Laibson,et al.  Golden Eggs and Hyperbolic Discounting , 1997 .

[26]  David I. Laibson,et al.  Life-cycle consumption and hyperbolic discount functions , 1998 .

[27]  B. Kőszegi,et al.  Exploiting Naïvete about Self-Control in the Credit Market , 2010 .

[28]  I. Fisher,et al.  The theory of interest , 1956 .

[29]  Philip H. Dybvig,et al.  Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity , 1983, Journal of Political Economy.

[30]  Kfir Eliaz,et al.  Contracting with Diversely Naive Agents , 2004 .