Technology adoption under time-differentiated market-based instruments for pollution control

Peak concentrations of ground-level ozone pose health risks to millions of U.S. citizens across the U.S. In order to reduce peak ozone concentrations, nitrogen oxide (NOx) emissions from the power sector, among others, have been regulated with technology-based standards or, more commonly in recent years, market-based instruments such as cap-and-trade programs. However, the lack of temporal flexibility in current designs of these market-based instruments limits their cost-effectiveness on days forecasted to have the highest levels of pollution, including ozone precursors such as NOx, and as further emission reductions are sought, the marginal cost of these approaches increases dramatically. In this paper, we compare three regulatory schemes for reducing NOx emissions on high-ozone days: time-differentiated pricing, which prices NOx emissions only on days with high-ozone concentrations; undifferentiated pricing, which represents current NOx emission regulations; and technology-based standards. We develop a novel model that captures for the first time both the short- and long-term response of generators, through redispatching and control technology adoption, to a dynamic pricing scheme such as time-differentiated pricing. Unlike prior studies on time-differentiated pricing, the heart of our model, a unit commitment model, accounts for inter-temporal constraints on power generation that may be crucial to accurately capturing the response of generators to a transient price signal. We apply this model to the Texas power system and find that while control technology adoption (specifically selective catalytic reduction) does occur at very high time-differentiated prices, time-differentiated pricing mainly affects emissions and costs through redispatching of gas- for coal-fired generation. Furthermore, we show that time-differentiated pricing, due to its targeted pricing mechanism, provides a more cost-effective approach than undifferentiated pricing or technology-based standards for reducing NOx emissions on high-ozone days, but is not cost-effective at reducing summer-wide NOx emissions. Our results illustrate the trade-offs between these regulatory approaches and suggest that states should consider dynamic pricing schemes such as time-differentiated pricing for achieving further reductions in peak ozone concentrations.

[1]  Tom Tietenberg,et al.  Tradeable permits for pollution control when emission location matters: What have we learned? , 1995 .

[2]  Robert N. Stavins,et al.  Incentive-Based Environmental Regulation: A New Era from an Old Idea , 1990 .

[3]  Denise L. Mauzerall,et al.  NOx emissions from large point sources : variability in ozone production, resulting health damages and economic costs , 2004 .

[4]  Ronald H. White,et al.  Health Benefits from Large-Scale Ozone Reduction in the United States , 2012, Environmental health perspectives.

[5]  David Allen,et al.  Dynamic Management of NOx and SO2 Emissions in the Texas and Mid-Atlantic Electric Power Systems and Implications for Air Quality. , 2016, Environmental science & technology.

[6]  B. Hobbs,et al.  Complementarity Modeling in Energy Markets , 2012 .

[7]  An Oligopoly Simulation of a Restructured ERCOT: Will Future Prices Be Competitive? , 2003 .

[8]  Byron Swift How Environmental Laws Work: An Analysis of the Utility Sector's Response to Regulation of Nitrogen Oxides and Sulfur Dioxide Under the Clean Air Act , 2001 .

[9]  Andres Ramos,et al.  Tight and Compact MILP Formulation of Start-Up and Shut-Down Ramping in Unit Commitment , 2013, IEEE Transactions on Power Systems.

[10]  Mort D. Webster,et al.  Optimal Selection of Sample Weeks for Approximating the Net Load in Generation Planning Problems , 2013 .

[11]  Lin Sun,et al.  Flexible NO(x) abatement from power plants in the eastern United States. , 2012, Environmental science & technology.

[12]  B. Hubbell,et al.  Estimating the National Public Health Burden Associated with Exposure to Ambient PM2.5 and Ozone , 2012, Risk analysis : an official publication of the Society for Risk Analysis.

[13]  Robert N. Stavins,et al.  What Can We Learn from the Grand Policy Experiment? Lessons from SO2 Allowance Trading , 1998 .

[14]  David A. Evans,et al.  The Evolution of NOx Control Policy for Coal-Fired Power Plants in the United States , 2003 .

[15]  Nicholas Z. Muller,et al.  Efficient Pollution Regulation: Getting the Prices Right , 2009 .

[16]  Neal Fann,et al.  The recent and future health burden of air pollution apportioned across U.S. sectors. , 2013, Environmental science & technology.

[17]  Michael T. Craig Reducing the contribution of the power sector to ground-level ozone pollution : an assessment of time-differentiated pricing of nitrogen oxide emissions , 2014 .

[18]  Jay Apt,et al.  Should a coal-fired power plant be replaced or retrofitted? , 2007, Environmental science & technology.