This article presents three measures of the distribution of actual and projected net benefits (benefits minus payroll taxes) from Social Security's Old-Age and Survivors Insurance (OASI) for people born between 1931 and 1960. The results are based on simulations with the Social Security Administration's Model of Income in the Near Term (MINT), which projects retirement income through 2020. The base sample for MINT is the U.S. Census Bureau's Survey of Income and Program Participation panels for 1990 to 1993, matched with Social Security administrative records. The study population is grouped into 5-year birth cohorts and then ranked by economic status in three ways. First, the population is divided into five groups on the basis of individual lifetime covered earnings, and their lifetime present values of OASI benefits received and payroll taxes paid are calculated. By this measure, OASI provides much higher benefits to the lowest quintile of earners than to other groups, but it becomes less redistributive toward lower earners in more recent birth cohorts. Second, people are ranked by shared lifetime covered earnings, and the values of shared benefits received and payroll taxes paid are computed. Individuals are assumed to split covered earnings, benefits, and payroll taxes with their spouses in the years they are married. By the shared covered earnings measure, OASI is still much more favorable to persons in the lower income quintiles, although to a lesser degree than when people are ranked by individual covered earnings. OASI becomes more progressive among recent cohorts, even as net lifetime benefits decline for the entire population. Finally, individuals are ranked on the basis of their shared permanent income from age 62, when they become eligible for early retirement benefits, until death. Their annual Social Security benefits are compared with the benefits they would have received if they had saved their payroll taxes in individual accounts and used the proceeds to buy either of two annuities that provide level payments from age 62 until death: a unisex annuity that is based on the average life expectancy of the birth cohort or an age-adjusted annuity that is based on the worker's own life expectancy. On the permanent income measure, OASI is generally more favorable to people in higher income quintiles. Moreover, it is particularly unfavorable to those in the lowest quintile. Because people in the lowest quintile have a shorter life expectancy, they receive OASI benefits for a shorter period. This group would receive greater benefits in retirement if they invested their payroll taxes in the age-adjusted annuity. OASI is more favorable to them than the unisex annuity, however, OASI is becoming more progressive in that the net benefits it provides drop more rapidly among higher income quintiles than lower ones. This article also examines how OASI affects individuals by educational attainment, race, and sex. On both the lifetime covered earnings and the permanent income measures, OASI is more favorable to workers with less education and more favorable to women. The results by race and ethnicity are mixed. When people are ranked by the present value of their shared lifetime covered earnings, OASI appears more favorable to non-Hispanic blacks and Hispanics than to non-Hispanic whites. When people are ranked by shared permanent income in retirement, however, OASI produces negative returns for both non-Hispanic blacks and non-Hispanic whites in the most recent birth cohorts, with non-Hispanic blacks faring relatively worse. The changes across cohorts occur partly because of changes in tax rates and benefits, but more importantly because of changing demographics and earnings patterns of the workforce. Of particular importance is the increasing share of beneficiaries who receive worker benefits instead of auxiliary benefits as wives or widows. OASI benefits are based on the lifetime covered earnings of current or former married couples, as well as on earned retirement benefits of individuals. The reduced importance of auxiliary benefits (due to the higher lifetime covered earnings of women) and the increased proportion of divorced retirees make OASI more progressive--even as net benefits decline--for current and future cohorts than for cohorts who retired in the 1990s. Analysis of these findings suggests that simulations of policy changes in Social Security must take into account the decreasing importance of auxiliary benefits across birth cohorts and the complex changes in individuals' marital histories.
[1]
B. Bosworth,et al.
The Trend in Lifetime Earnings Inequality and its Impact on the Distribution of Retirement Income
,
2001
.
[2]
Howard N. Fullerton,et al.
Labor force participation: 75 years of change, 1950-98 and 1998-2025
,
1999
.
[3]
Barry Bosworth,et al.
Modeling Income in the Near Term: Projections of Retirement Income through 2020 for the 1931-60 Birth Cohorts
,
1999
.
[4]
H. Hayghe.
Developments in Women's Labor Force Participation
,
1997
.
[5]
H. Hayghe,et al.
Working Wives' Contributions to Family Incomes.
,
1993
.
[6]
J. R. Wetzel.
American families: 75 years of change.
,
1990
.
[7]
H. Hayghe.
Family Members in the Work Force.
,
1990
.
[8]
B. Butrica.
Methods in modeling income in the near term (MINT I)
,
2001
.
[9]
H. Iams,et al.
Divorced women at retirement: projections of economic well-being in the near future.
,
2000,
Social security bulletin.
[10]
H. Iams,et al.
Using data for couples to project the distributional effects of changes in Social Security policy.
,
1999,
Social security bulletin.
[11]
H. Iams,et al.
Projecting retirement income of future retirees with panel data: results from the modeling income in the near-term (MINT) project.
,
1999,
Social security bulletin.
[12]
H. Iams,et al.
Projecting Social Security earnings: past is prologue.
,
1997,
Social security bulletin.
[13]
H. Aaron.
Demographic Effects on the Equity of Social Security Benefits
,
1977
.