Decision Ambiguity and Incumbent Brand Advantage

This article examines the role of decision ambiguity in judgments that consumers make about an incumbent (the brand a consumer currently uses) versus an attack brand (a new, superior competitor). It is hypothesized that decision ambiguity creates an advantage for the incumbent. A conceptualization of decision ambiguity is offered. In three experiments, factors that can cause decision ambiguity are manipulated and their effects on preference for the incumbent are investigated. The results underscore the role of decision ambiguity in incumbent brand advantage. In two other experiments, boundary conditions are examined. T his research focuses on the advantages of incumbency. The term incumbent refers to the brand that a consumer first chooses in a product category. A brand may achieve incumbent status by being the first brand chosen by consumers entering a mature product class or by being a pioneer in a new product class. An incumbency advantage occurs when consumers prefer the incumbent to an objectively superior but later-encountered competitor (referred to as the attack brand). The objectives of this research are to examine conditions under which an incumbent advantage obtains and to conduct an exploratory investigation of the psychological processes that underlie it. Research in marketing has not been specific about either the processes or the conditions that result in an incumbency advantage. Although research on the related topic of brand loyalty has emphasized the role of emotional commitment or ego involvement in repeat purchase behavior (e.g., Jacoby 197 1; Jacoby and Chestnut 1978), other psychological processes are surely operative. On the basis of behavioral decision theory research, I propose a framework that offers a different explanation for consumer repeat purchase behavior. In addition, this framework offers an explanation of the pioneering advantage that is consistent with, but independent of, prior research (e.g., Carpenter and Nakamoto 1989; Kardes and Kalyanaram 1992; Schmalensee 1982). With a few notable exceptions in the domain of the pioneering advantage (Carpenter and Nakamoto 1989; Kardes and Kalyanaram 1992; Kardes et al. 1993), research in marketing has not provided a psychological account of the incumbency advantage. However, behavioral decision theory research offers some suggestions. For example, Samuelson and Zeckhauser (1988) showed that people prefer a previously chosen option over others. This pervasive tendency labeled the "status quo bias" has been demonstrated across a range of decisions. Samuelson and Zeckhauser (1988) invoked a variety of psychological mechanisms to explain the phenomenon, including commitment induced by sunk costs, regret avoidance, cognitive misperception, and feeling of control. However, Samuelson and Zeckhauser (1988) were silent with respect to conditions that would make such biases present, absent, or even reversed (cf. Biehal and Chakravarti 1983). The present research identifies the decision characteristics that can increase or decrease the likelihood of the status quo bias. The central premise of this research is that the incumbency advantage will vary as a function of the level of ambiguity in the decision environment.

[1]  S. Oskamp OVERCONFIDENCE IN CASE-STUDY JUDGMENTS. , 1965, Journal of consulting psychology.

[2]  A. Tversky Elimination by aspects: A theory of choice. , 1972 .

[3]  Paul Slovic,et al.  Dimensional Commensurability and Cue Utilization in Comparative Judgment. , 1974 .

[4]  M. Zanna,et al.  Attitudinal qualities relating to the strength of the attitude-behavior relationship☆ , 1978 .

[5]  J. Jacoby,et al.  Brand Loyalty: Measurement and Management , 1978 .

[6]  R. Hogarth,et al.  Confidence in judgment: Persistence of the illusion of validity. , 1978 .

[7]  J. March Bounded rationality, ambiguity, and the engineering of choice , 1978 .

[8]  H. J. Einhorn,et al.  Cognitive processes in choice and decision behavior , 1979 .

[9]  R. Schmalensee Product Differentiation Advantages of Pioneering Brands , 1980 .

[10]  B. Brehmer In one word: Not from experience. , 1980 .

[11]  J. E. Tschirgi,et al.  Sensible reasoning: A hypothesis about hypotheses. , 1980 .

[12]  B. Fischhoff,et al.  Reasons for confidence. , 1980 .

[13]  Christopher P. Puto,et al.  Adding Asymmetrically Dominated Alternatives: Violations of Regularity & the Similarity Hypothesis. , 1981 .

[14]  Hillel J. Einhorn,et al.  Judgment under uncertainty: Learning from experience and suboptimal rules in decision making , 1982 .

[15]  B. Fischhoff,et al.  Calibration of probabilities: the state of the art to 1980 , 1982 .

[16]  William R. Swinyard,et al.  Attitude-Behavior Consistency: The Impact of Product Trial versus Advertising: , 1983 .

[17]  Gabriel J. Biehal,et al.  Information Accessibility as a Moderator of Consumer Choice , 1983 .

[18]  Stephen J. Hoch,et al.  Consumer Learning: Advertising and the Ambiguity of Product Experience , 1986 .

[19]  Gabriel J. Biehal,et al.  Consumers' Use of Memory and External Information in Choice: Macro and Micro Perspectives , 1986 .

[20]  J. Klayman,et al.  Confirmation, Disconfirmation, and Informa-tion in Hypothesis Testing , 1987 .

[21]  J. W. Hutchinson,et al.  Dimensions of Consumer Expertise , 1987 .

[22]  William Samuelson,et al.  Status quo bias in decision making , 1988 .

[23]  Jack M. Feldman,et al.  Self-generated validity and other effects of measurement on belief, attitude, intention, and behavior. , 1988 .

[24]  Dane K. Peterson,et al.  Confidence, uncertainty, and the use of information , 1988 .

[25]  Jonathan Baron,et al.  Ambiguity and rationality , 1988 .

[26]  John G. Lynch,et al.  Choices from Sets Including Remembered Brands: Use of Recalled Attributes and Prior Overall Evaluations , 1988 .

[27]  Amitava Chattopadhyay,et al.  The Situational Importance of Recall and Inference in Consumer Decision Making , 1988 .

[28]  J. Klayman,et al.  Hypothesis testing in rule discovery: Strategy, structure, and content. , 1989 .

[29]  Stephen J. Hoch,et al.  Ambiguity, Processing Strategy, and Advertising-Evidence Interactions , 1989 .

[30]  Stephen J. Hoch,et al.  Managing What Consumers Learn from Experience , 1989 .

[31]  Gregory S. Carpenter,et al.  Consumer Preference Formation and Pioneering Advantage , 1989 .

[32]  Steven J. Sherman,et al.  The influence of unique features and direction of comparison of preferences , 1989 .

[33]  Bryan Gibson,et al.  The role of attribute knowledge and overall evaluations in comparative judgment , 1991 .

[34]  A. Tversky,et al.  Loss Aversion in Riskless Choice: A Reference-Dependent Model , 1991 .

[35]  A. Tversky,et al.  Preference and belief: Ambiguity and competence in choice under uncertainty , 1991 .

[36]  Amitava Chattopadhyay,et al.  Transitions in Preference over Time: The Effects of Memory on Message Persuasiveness , 1992 .

[37]  A. Tversky,et al.  Choice in Context: Tradeoff Contrast and Extremeness Aversion , 1992 .

[38]  Colin Camerer,et al.  Recent developments in modeling preferences: Uncertainty and ambiguity , 1992 .

[39]  G. Kalyanaram,et al.  Order-of-Entry Effects on Consumer Memory and Judgment: An Information Integration Perspective , 1992 .

[40]  G. Kalyanaram,et al.  Brand Retrieval, Consideration Set Composition, Consumer Choice, and the Pioneering Advantage , 1993 .

[41]  M. F. Luce,et al.  Correlation, conflict, and choice. , 1993 .

[42]  F. Kardes,et al.  Direction of comparison, expected feature correlation, and the set-size effect in preference judgment , 1993 .