A Theory of Political Transitions

We develop a theory of political transitions inspired in part by the experiences of Western Europe and Latin America. Nondemocratic societies are controlled by a rich elite. The initially disenfranchised poor can contest power by threatening social unrest or revolution and this may force the elite to democratize. Democracy may not consolidate because it is more redistributive than a nondemocratic regime, and this gives the elite an incentive to mount a coup. Because inequality makes democracy more costly for the elite, highly unequal societies are less likely to consolidate democracy and may end up oscillating between regimes or in a nondemocratic repressive regime. An unequal society is likely to experience fiscal volatility, but the relationship between inequality and redistribution is nonmonotonic; societies with intermediate levels of inequality consolidate democracy and redistribute more than both very equal and very unequal countries. We also show that asset redistribution, such as educational and land reform, may be used to consolidate both democratic and nondemocratic regimes.

[1]  D. Rodrik Democracies Pay Higher Wages , 1998 .

[2]  A. Velasco,et al.  The Tragedy of the Commons and Economic Growth: Why Does Capital Flow from Poor to Rich Countries? , 1992, Journal of Political Economy.

[3]  Aldo Rustichini,et al.  Social conflict and growth , 1996 .

[4]  Terence H. Qualter,et al.  Democracy and the Market , 1991 .

[5]  Daron Acemoglu,et al.  Why Did West Extend the Franchise? Democracy, Ineqiality and Growth in Historical Perspective , 2000 .

[6]  Matthew Ellman,et al.  Electoral Competition Under the Threat of Political Unrest , 1999 .

[7]  Roberto Perotti,et al.  Fiscal Policy in Latin America , 1997, NBER Macroeconomics Annual.

[8]  J. D. Powell Political mobilization of the Venezuelan peasant. , 1971 .

[9]  Léonard Wantchekon,et al.  Strategic Voting in Conditions of Political Instability , 1999 .

[10]  Eliana A. Cardoso,et al.  Latin America's Economy: Diversity, Trends, and Conflicts , 1995 .

[11]  G. O'donnell Modernization and bureaucratic-authoritarianism : studies in South American politics , 1973 .

[12]  R. Kaufman,et al.  The Political Economy of Latin American Populism , 1991 .

[13]  W. C. Thiesenhusen,et al.  Searching for agrarian reform in Latin America , 1989 .

[14]  J. Sachs Social Conflict and Populist Policies in Latin America , 1989 .

[15]  R. Collier Paths toward Democracy: The Working Class and Elites in Western Europe and South America , 1999 .

[16]  James Dunkerley The political economy of democratic transitions , 1997 .

[17]  Alice H. Amsden,et al.  Bringing the State Back In: The State and Taiwan's Economic Development , 1985 .

[18]  John E. Roemer,et al.  RATIONALIZING REVOLUTIONARY IDEOLOGY , 1985 .

[19]  P. Dorner Latin American Land Reforms in Theory and Practice: A Retrospective Analysis , 1992 .

[20]  Gary Gereffi,et al.  Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries. , 1990 .

[21]  R. Bénabou Unequal Societies , 1996 .

[22]  C. Vilas,et al.  Between earthquakes and volcanoes : market, state, and the revolutions in Central America , 1997 .

[23]  John E. Roemer,et al.  Why the poor do not expropriate the rich: an old argument in new garb , 1998 .

[24]  Robert H. Trudeau Guatemalan Politics: The Popular Struggle for Democracy , 1993 .

[25]  Randall Wright Taxes, redistribution, and growth , 1996 .

[26]  T. Verdier The Rise and Fall of Elites: A Theory of Economic Development and Social Polarization in Rent-seeking Societies , 1996 .

[27]  J. Gusfield,et al.  Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the Making of the Modern World , 1967 .

[28]  J. Handy,et al.  Gift of the devil: A history of Guatemala , 1984 .

[29]  Barrington. Moore,et al.  Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the Making of the Modern World , 1967 .

[30]  Allan H. Meltzer,et al.  A Rational Theory of the Size of Government , 1981, Journal of Political Economy.

[31]  Kurt Weyland Democracy without equity : failures of reform in Brazil , 1996 .

[32]  L. Jarvis,et al.  The unraveling of Chile's agrarian reform, 1973-1986. , 1989 .

[33]  Herschel I. Grossman Production, Appropriation, and Land Reform , 1994 .

[34]  Daron Acemoglu,et al.  Was Prometheus Unbound by Chance? Risk, Diversification, and Growth , 1997, Journal of Political Economy.

[35]  A. Alesina,et al.  Income Distribution, Political Instability, and Investment , 1993 .

[36]  A. Horowitz Time Paths of Land Reform: A Theoretical Model of Reform Dynamics , 1993 .

[37]  R. Vassilev Problems of democratic transition and consolidation in post-communist Bulgaria / , 2000 .

[38]  Wanyong Kuo Economic development of Taiwan , 1968 .

[39]  D. Rustow Transitions to Democracy: Toward a Dynamic Model , 1970 .

[40]  Efe A. Ok,et al.  Social Mobility and the Demand for Redistribution: the Poum Hypothesis , 1998 .

[41]  E. Amenta,et al.  Taxation and Democracy: Swedish, British, and American Approaches to Financing the Modern State. , 1995 .

[42]  Philippe C. Schmitter,et al.  Transitions from Authoritarian Rule: Tentative Conclusions about Uncertain Democracies , 1990 .

[43]  Torsten Persson,et al.  Is Inequality Harmful for Growth? Theory and Evidence , 1991 .

[44]  S. Lipset Some Social Requisites of Democracy: Economic Development and Political Legitimacy , 1959, American Political Science Review.

[45]  D. Rock,et al.  Argentina, 1516-1987: From Spanish Colonization to Alfonsín , 1985 .

[46]  M. Gasiorowski Economic Crisis and Political Regime Change: An Event History Analysis , 1995, American Political Science Review.

[47]  Jeffery M. Paige Coffee and Power: Revolution and the Rise of Democracy in Central America , 1997 .

[48]  A. Janvry Latin American land reforms in theory and practice: A retrospective analysis: Peter Dorner, (The University of Wisconsin Press, Madison WI, 1992), pp. ix + 108 , 1994 .