An analysis of forestry carbon sequestration as a response to climate change.

preface COPENHAGEN CONSENSUS ON CLIMATE copenhAgen consensus on climAte The Copenhagen Consensus Center has commissioned 21 papers to examine the costs and benefits of different solutions to global warming. The project’s goal is to answer the question: “If the global community wants to spend up to, say $250 billion per year over the next 10 years to diminish the adverse effects of climate changes, and to do most good for the world, which solutions would yield the greatest net benefits?” The series of papers is divided into Assessment Papers and Perspective Papers. Each Assessment Paper outlines the costs and benefits of one way to respond to global warming. Each Perspective Paper reviews the assumptions and analyses made within an Assessment Paper. It is hoped that, as a body of work, this research will provide a foundation for an informed debate about the best way to respond to this threat. Terrestrial ecosystems store approximately 1 trillion tons of CO2 in the biomass of living trees and plants. Current estimates suggest that it would be possible to increase this carbon efficiently in order to reduce the future damages of climate change. The methods that could be used include afforestation (planting old agricultural land in trees), reduced deforestation, and forest management. Current estimates in the literature accounting for opportunity costs and implementation and management costs suggest that an additional 6.8 billion tons CO2 per year may be sequestered in forests by 2030 for $30 per ton CO2. Around 42% of this would arise from avoided deforestation, with the rest roughly equally split between afforestation and forest management options. Analysis indicates that if society follows an “optimal” carbon abatement policy, as defined in Nordhaus (2009), forestry could accomplish roughly 30% of total abatement over the century. If society instead places strict limits on emissions in order to meet a 2oC temperature increase limitation, then the component forestry provides lowers overall abatement costs by as much as 50%. The benefit cost ratio in the optimal scenario is 1.0, while it is 1.8 in the 2oC limiting case. The results of the benefit cost analysis do not substantially change with a lower interest rate, and they also do not substantially change when transactions costs are included. This rather optimistic economic analysis is useful, but it does not account directly for leakage. Given that the literature suggests that leakage could be as large as 90% 100%, it would have large implications for costs, potentially reducing the benefit cost ratio below 1. Importantly, leakage can only be reduced by including more countries into the control program. The paper also does not account for other potential benefits of adding forestland over time. These benefits are ecological in nature, and they are difficult to measure systematically across the globe. They do, however, represent a potentially large, additional, benefit of a forestry carbon sequestration program.

[1]  B. Sohngen,et al.  Set-asides for carbon sequestration: implications for permanence and leakage , 2009 .

[2]  P. Ramchandani,et al.  A question of balance , 2004, Nature.

[3]  M. Grieg-Gran The Cost of Avoiding Deforestation: Update of the Report prepared for the Stern Review of the Economics of Climate Change , 2008 .

[4]  Werner A. Kurz,et al.  A 70-YEAR RETROSPECTIVE ANALYSIS OF CARBON FLUXES IN THE CANADIAN FOREST SECTOR , 1999 .

[5]  R. Houghton The annual net flux of carbon to the atmosphere from changes in land use 1850–1990* , 1999 .

[6]  B. Sohngen,et al.  The influence of conversion of forest types on carbon sequestration and other ecosystem services in the South Central United States , 2006 .

[7]  Birger Solberg,et al.  Potential and Economic Efficiency of Carbon Sequestration in Forest Biomass Through Silvicultural Management , 1994 .

[8]  Michael Obersteiner,et al.  Global cost estimates of reducing carbon emissions through avoided deforestation , 2008, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[9]  R. Sedjo Forests: a tool to moderate global warming , 1989 .

[10]  B. Sohngen,et al.  Stocks and Flows Carbon Inventory and Mitigation Potential of the Russian Forest and Land Base , 2006 .

[11]  Roger A. Sedjo,et al.  The economics of managing carbon via forestry: Assessment of existing studies , 1995 .

[12]  Simon Buckle,et al.  Mitigation of climate change , 2009, The Daunting Climate Change.

[13]  Kenneth R. Richards,et al.  A Review of Forest Carbon Sequestration Cost Studies: A Dozen Years of Research , 2004 .

[14]  Catrinus Jepma,et al.  Climate Change Policy , 2017 .

[15]  William D. Nordhaus,et al.  Warming the World: Economic Models of Global Warming , 2000 .

[16]  Jacinto F. Fabiosa,et al.  Use of U.S. Croplands for Biofuels Increases Greenhouse Gases Through Emissions from Land-Use Change , 2008, Science.

[17]  THE FOREST RESOURCES OF THE UNITED STATES. , 1896, Science.

[18]  B. Sohngen,et al.  An Optimal Control Model of Forest Carbon Sequestration , 2003 .

[19]  Robert N. Stavins,et al.  Land-Use Change and Carbon Sinks: Econometric Estimation of the Carbon Sequestration Supply Function , 2005 .

[20]  Bruce A. McCarl,et al.  Greenhouse Gas Mitigation Potential in U.S. Forestry and Agriculture , 2005 .

[21]  Valentina Bosetti,et al.  Forestry and the Carbon Market Response to Stabilize Climate , 2007 .

[22]  B. Sohngen,et al.  Extending timber rotations: carbon and cost implications , 2008 .

[23]  Christopher E. Clarke A Question of Balance , 2008 .

[24]  Robert N. Stavins,et al.  The Costs of Carbon Sequestration: A Revealed-Preference Approach , 1999 .

[25]  R. Houghton Revised estimates of the annual net flux of carbon to the atmosphere from changes in land use and land management 1850 – 2000 , 2003 .

[26]  G. Cornelis van Kooten,et al.  How costly are carbon offsets? A meta-analysis of carbon forest sinks , 2004 .

[27]  Brent Sohngen and Roger Sedjo Carbon Sequestration in Global Forests Under Different Carbon Price Regimes , 2006 .

[28]  John M. Antle,et al.  Spatial heterogeneity, contract design, and the efficiency of carbon sequestration policies for agriculture , 2003 .

[29]  John M. Reilly,et al.  Human-induced climate change : an interdisciplinary assessment , 2007 .

[30]  J. M. Callaway,et al.  Minimum Cost Strategies for Sequestering Carbon in Forests , 1999 .

[31]  Sandra Brown,et al.  Measuring leakage from carbon projects in open economies: a stop timber harvesting project in Bolivia as a case study , 2004 .

[32]  Brian C. Murray,et al.  Economic consequences of consideration of permanence, leakage and additionality for soil carbon sequestration projects , 2007 .

[33]  C. Robledo,et al.  INITIAL ANALYSIS ON THE MITIGATION POTENTIAL IN THE FORESTRY SECTOR , 2007 .

[34]  Thomas W. Hertel,et al.  The Role of Forestry in Carbon Sequestration in General Equilibrium Models , 2008, GTAP Working Paper.

[35]  B. Sohngen,et al.  Human-Induced Climate Change: A sensitivity analysis of forest carbon sequestration , 2007 .

[36]  C. Perry,et al.  Forest Resources of the United States, 2007 , 2009 .

[37]  N. Stanietsky,et al.  The interaction of TIGIT with PVR and PVRL2 inhibits human NK cell cytotoxicity , 2009, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[38]  Thomas Mauldin,et al.  An Econometric Analysis of the Costs of Sequestering Carbon in Forests , 1999 .

[39]  L. Lipper,et al.  Climate Change Mitigation Measures in the Agro-forestry Sector and Biodiversity Futures Abatement and Transaction Costs of Carbon-sink Projects Involving Smallholders Abatement and Transaction Costs of Carbon-sink Projects Involving Smallholders , 2022 .