Subjective and Objective Risk Tolerance: Implications for Optimal Portfolios

The distinction between subjective and objective risk tolerance is illustrated by expected utility analyses of portfolios. Optimal portfolios were derived for one, 5, and 20 year investment horizons for 6 major financial asset categories. The important aspects of objective risk tolerance are the proportion of an investor's total wealth (including human wealth) in financial assets, and the investment horizon. Even investors with very low subjective risk tolerance levels should have aggressive portfolios if their horizons are 20 years or more.

[1]  Martha A. Starr,et al.  Family finances in the U.S.: recent evidence from the Survey of Consumer Finances , 1997 .

[2]  Charles J. Delaney,et al.  Portfolio Management , 1995, Encyclopedia of Creativity, Invention, Innovation and Entrepreneurship.

[3]  H. Markowitz,et al.  Mean-Variance versus Direct Utility Maximization , 1984 .

[4]  Benefits for Environmental Decisions,et al.  Choice Under Uncertainty: Problems Solved And Unsolved , 1990 .

[5]  Sherman D. Hanna,et al.  Real income growth and optimal credit use , 1994 .

[6]  M. Milevsky,et al.  Asset allocation, life expectancy and shortfall , 1994 .

[7]  Sherman D. Hanna,et al.  Factors Related to Risk Tolerance , 1996 .

[8]  P. Samuelson LIFETIME PORTFOLIO SELECTION BY DYNAMIC STOCHASTIC PROGRAMMING , 1969 .

[9]  Miles S. Kimball,et al.  Preference Parameters and Behavioral Heterogeneity: An Experimental Approach in the Health and Retirement Survey , 1995 .

[10]  L. J. Savage,et al.  The Utility Analysis of Choices Involving Risk , 1948, Journal of Political Economy.

[11]  M. Blume,et al.  The Demand for Risky Assets , 1975 .

[12]  Paul Wonnacott,et al.  The Marginal Utility of Income Does not Increase: Borrowing, Lending, and Friedman-Savage Gambles , 1980 .

[13]  R. Jagannathan,et al.  Why should older people invest less in stock than younger people , 1996 .

[14]  Sherman D. Hanna,et al.  Efficient Portfolios for Saving for College , 1997 .

[15]  Miles S. Kimball Farmers' Cooperatives as Behavior Toward Risk , 1988 .

[16]  P. Schoemaker The Expected Utility Model: Its Variants, Purposes, Evidence and Limitations , 1982 .

[17]  D. Malliaropulos ARE LONG-HORIZON STOCK RETURNS PREDICTABLE? A BOOTSTRAP ANALYSIS , 1996 .

[18]  J. Muellbauer,et al.  Economics and consumer behavior , 1980 .

[19]  M. Blume,et al.  The Asset Structure of Individual Portfolios and Some Implications for Utility Functions , 1975 .

[20]  E. Fama Portfolio Analysis in a Stable Paretian Market , 1965 .

[21]  R. Mehra,et al.  THE EQUITY PREMIUM A Puzzle , 1985 .

[22]  P. Samuelson Asset allocation could be dangerous to your health , 1990 .

[23]  Sherman D. Hanna,et al.  Investment Portfolios and Human Wealth , 1996 .

[24]  Martin L. Leibowitz,et al.  Asset allocation under shortfall constraints , 1991 .

[25]  C. Peake Why Should Older People Invest Less in Stocks than Younger People , 1997 .

[26]  K. Arrow Essays in the theory of risk-bearing , 1958 .

[27]  R. Avery,et al.  Financial characteristics of high-income families , 1986 .

[28]  Steven J. Cochran,et al.  NEW EVIDENCE ON PREDICTABILITY IN WORLD EQUITY MARKETS , 1995 .

[29]  Optimal holding period for assets that must be liquidated: A certainty equivalent wealth approach , 1995 .

[30]  F. Black Capital Market Equilibrium with Restricted Borrowing , 1972 .

[31]  B. Malkiel A Random Walk Down Wall Street , 1973 .

[32]  Sanford J. Grossman,et al.  The Determinants of the Variability of Stock Market Prices , 1980 .

[33]  Martin L. Leibowitz,et al.  Shortfall risk and the asset allocation decision , 1989 .

[34]  Stocks for the long run : a guide to selecting markets for long-term growth , 1994 .

[35]  Sherman D. Hanna Risk Aversion and Optimal Insurance Deductibles , 1989 .