Do Wealth Fluctuations Generate Time-Varying Risk Aversion? Micro-Evidence on Individuals' Asset Allocation

We use data from the PSID to investigate how households' portfolio allocations change in response to wealth fluctuations. Persistent habits, consumption commitments, and subsistence levels can generate time-varying risk aversion with the consequence that when the level of liquid wealth changes, the proportion a household invests in risky assets should also change in the same direction. In contrast, our analysis shows that the share of liquid assets that households invest in risky assets is not affected by wealth changes. Instead, one of the major drivers of households' portfolio allocation seems to be inertia: households rebalance only very slowly following inflows and outflows or capital gains and losses.

[1]  Joshua S. White,et al.  External Habit Formation and the Home Bias Puzzle , 2002 .

[2]  Michele Boldrin,et al.  Habit Persistence, Asset Returns, and the Business Cycle , 2001 .

[3]  Prospect Theory and Asset Prices , 1999 .

[4]  Orazio Attanasio,et al.  Stock-Market Participation, Intertemporal Substitution, and Risk-Aversion , 2003 .

[5]  M. Lettau Idiosyncratic Risk and Volatility Bounds, or Can Models with Idiosyncratic Risk Solve the Equity Premium Puzzle? , 2001, Review of Economics and Statistics.

[6]  Michael Haliassos,et al.  Why Do So Few Hold Stocks , 1995 .

[7]  Douglas Holtz-Eakin,et al.  The Carnegie Conjecture: Some Empirical Evidence , 1992 .

[8]  A. Deaton The Analysis of Household Surveys : A Microeconometric Approach to Development Policy , 1997 .

[9]  Gur Huberman,et al.  Performance and Employer Stock in 401(k) Plans , 2004 .

[10]  Terrance Odean,et al.  Are Investors Reluctant to Realize Their Losses? , 1996 .

[11]  Andrew B. Abel,et al.  Asset Prices Under Habit Formation and Catching Up with the Joneses , 1990 .

[12]  Urban Jermann Asset pricing in production economies , 1998 .

[13]  Mark D. Schroder,et al.  An Isomorphism between Asset Pricing Models with and Without Linear Habit Formation , 2000 .

[14]  J. Parker The Consumption Risk of the Stock Market , 2001 .

[15]  J. Campbell,et al.  By Force of Habit: A Consumption‐Based Explanation of Aggregate Stock Market Behavior , 1995, Journal of Political Economy.

[16]  Enrichetta Ravina Keeping Up with the Joneses: Evidence from Micro Data , 2005 .

[17]  J. Stock,et al.  Instrumental Variables Regression with Weak Instruments , 1994 .

[18]  Shlomo Benartzi,et al.  Excessive Extrapolation and the Allocation of 401(k) Accounts to Company Stock , 2001 .

[19]  N. Mankiw,et al.  The Consumption of Stockholders and Non-Stockholders , 1990 .

[20]  João F. Cocco,et al.  Portfolio Choice in the Presence of Housing , 2000 .

[21]  P. Samuelson Lifetime Portfolio Selection by Dynamic Stochastic Programming , 1969 .

[22]  Raj Chetty,et al.  Consumption Commitments: Neoclassical Foundations for Habit Formation , 2005 .

[23]  Darrell Duffie,et al.  Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers , 1996, Journal of Political Economy.

[24]  J. Heaton,et al.  MARKET FRICTIONS, SAVINGS BEHAVIOR, AND PORTFOLIO CHOICE , 1997, Macroeconomic Dynamics.

[25]  Karen E. Dynan Habit Formation in Consumer Preferences: Evidence from Panel Data , 2000 .

[26]  M. Haliassos,et al.  Household Stockholding in Europe: Where Do We Stand and Where Do We Go? , 2002, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[27]  Alexander Michaelides,et al.  Portfolio Choice with Internal Habit Formation: A Life-Cycle Model with Uninsurable Labor Income Risk , 2002 .

[28]  Francisco J. Gomes,et al.  Optimal Life-Cycle Asset Allocation: Understanding the Empirical Evidence , 2003 .

[29]  Christian Gollier,et al.  Risk Vulnerability and the temper-ing E ect of Background Risk , 1996 .

[30]  P. Samuelson LIFETIME PORTFOLIO SELECTION BY DYNAMIC STOCHASTIC PROGRAMMING , 1969 .

[31]  Rui Yao,et al.  Optimal Consumption and Portfolio Choices with Risky Housing and Borrowing Constraints , 2004 .

[32]  M. Blume,et al.  The Demand for Risky Assets , 1975 .

[33]  Annette Vissing-Jorgensen,et al.  Towards an Explanation of Household Portfolio Choice Heterogeneity: Nonfinancial Income and Participation Cost Structures , 2002 .

[34]  J. Heaton,et al.  Portfolio Choice and Asset Prices: The Importance of Entrepreneurial Risk , 2000 .

[35]  Household Stockholding in Europe , 2002 .

[36]  Charles H. Whiteman,et al.  Habit formation: a resolution of the equity premium puzzle? , 2002 .

[37]  E. Prescott,et al.  The Equity Premium in Retrospect , 2003 .

[38]  N. Mankiw,et al.  The Equity Premium and the Concentration of Aggregate Shocks , 1986 .

[39]  C. Carroll,et al.  Buffer-Stock Saving and the Life Cycle/Permanent Income Hypothesis , 1996 .

[40]  Francisco J. Gomes,et al.  Portfolio Choice with Internal Habit Formation: A Life-Cycle Model with Uninsurable Labour Income Risk , 2003 .

[41]  Miquel Faig,et al.  Portfolio Choice in the Presence of Personal Illiquid Projects , 2002 .

[42]  Gurdip Bakshi,et al.  The Spirit of Capitalism and Stock-Market Prices , 1996 .

[43]  Miles S. Kimball,et al.  Preference Parameters and Behavioral Heterogeneity: An Experimental Approach in the Health and Retirement Survey , 1995 .

[44]  Julie R. Agnew,et al.  Portfolio Choice and Trading in a Large 401(k) Plan , 2003 .

[45]  Marcelo J. Moreira A Conditional Likelihood Ratio Test for Structural Models , 2003 .

[46]  Pascal J. Maenhout,et al.  Consumption and Portfolio Choice over the Life Cycle , 2005 .

[47]  S. Zeldes,et al.  Optimal Consumption with Stochastic Income: Deviations from Certainty Equivalence , 1989 .

[48]  S. Zeldes,et al.  How do household portfolio shares vary with age? Unpub-lished working paper , 2000 .

[49]  James P. Smith,et al.  The Measurement and Structure of Household Wealth , 1999 .

[50]  William Samuelson,et al.  Status quo bias in decision making , 1988 .