The U.S. proposed carbon tariffs, WTO scrutiny and China’s responses

With governments from around the world trying to hammer out a post-2012 climate change agreement, no one would disagree that a U.S. commitment to cut greenhouse gas emissions is essential to such a global pact. However, despite U.S. president Obama’s announcement to push for a commitment to cut U.S. greenhouse gas emissions by 17% by 2020, in reality it is questionable whether U.S. Congress will agree to specific emissions cuts, although they are not ambitious at all from the perspectives of both the EU and developing countries, without the imposition of carbon tariffs on Chinese products to the U.S. market, even given China’s own announcement to voluntarily seek to reduce its carbon intensity by 40–45% over the same period. This dilemma is partly attributed to flaws in current international climate negotiations, which have been focused on commitments on the two targeted dates of 2020 and 2050. However, if the international climate change negotiations continue on their current course without extending the commitment period to 2030, which would really open the possibility for the U.S. and China to make the commitments that each wants from the other, the inclusion of border carbon adjustment measures seems essential to secure passage of any U.S. legislation capping its own greenhouse gas emissions. Moreover, the joint WTO-UNEP report indicates that border carbon adjustment measures might be allowed under the existing WTO rules, depending on their specific design features and the specific conditions for implementing them. Against this background, this paper argues that, on the U.S. side, there is a need to minimize the potential conflicts with WTO provisions in designing such border carbon adjustment measures. The U.S. also needs to explore, with its trading partners, ccooperative sectoral approaches to advancing low-carbon technologies and/or concerted mitigation efforts in a given sector at the international level. Moreover, to increase the prospects for a successful WTO defence of the Waxman-Markey type of border adjustment provision, there should be: 1) a period of good faith efforts to reach agreements among the countries concerned before imposing such trade measures; 2) consideration of alternatives to trade provisions that could reasonably be expected to fulfill the same function but are not inconsistent or less inconsistent with the relevant WTO provisions; and 3) trade provisions that should allow importers to submit equivalent emission reduction units that are recognized by international treaties to cover the carbon contents of imported products. Meanwhile, being targeted by such border carbon adjustment measures, China needs to, at the right time, indicate a serious commitment to address climate change issues to challenge the legitimacy of the U.S. imposing carbon tariffs by signaling well ahead that it will take on binding absolute emission caps around the year 2030, and needs the three transitional periods of increasing climate obligations before taking on absolute emissions caps. This paper argues that there is a clear need within a climate regime to define comparable efforts towards climate mitigation and adaptation to discipline the use of unilateral trade measures at the international level. As exemplified by export tariffs that China applied on its own during 2006–08, the paper shows that defining the comparability of climate efforts can be to China’s advantage. Furthermore, given the fact that, in volume terms, energy-intensive manufacturing in China values 7 to 8 times that of India, and thus carbon tariffs have a greater impact on China than on India, the paper questions whether China should hold the same stance on this issue as India as it does now, although the two largest developing countries should continue to take a common position on other key issues in international climate change negotiations.

[1]  C. Carraro,et al.  Climate Policy and the Optimal Balance between Mitigation, Adaptation and Unavoided Damage , 2010 .

[2]  M. Thring World Energy Outlook , 1977 .

[3]  K. Neuhoff,et al.  Cambridge Working Papers in Economics CWPE 0409 Border Tax Adjustments: A Feasible way to Support Stringent Emission Trading , 2007 .

[4]  C. Cattaneo Migrants’ International Transfers and Educational Expenditure: Empirical Evidence from Albania , 2010 .

[5]  William Oduro,et al.  Changes in Beliefs and Perceptions About the Natural Environment in the Forest-Savanna Transitional Zone of Ghana: The Influence of Religion , 2010 .

[6]  ZhongXiang Zhang,et al.  Multilateral Trade Measures in a Post-2012 Climate Change Regime?: What Can Be Taken from the Montreal Protocol and the WTO? , 2009 .

[7]  ZhongXiang Zhang,et al.  Greenhouse Gas Emissions Trading and the World Trading System , 1998, Journal of World Trade.

[8]  中華人民共和国国家統計局 China statistical yearbook , 1988 .

[9]  Matthew Genasci Border Tax Adjustments and Emissions Trading: The Implications of International Trade Law for Policy Design , 2008 .

[10]  ZhongXiang Zhang,et al.  The economics of energy policy in China : implications for global climate change , 1998 .

[11]  A. Rodríguez‐Pose,et al.  Returns to Migration, Education, and Externalities in the European Union , 2010 .

[12]  S. Charnovitz,et al.  Trade and Climate Change: A Report by the United Nations Environment Programme and the World Trade Organization by UNEP and the WTO Geneva: WTO, 2009 , 2010 .

[13]  Carlo Scarpa,et al.  Do competition and ownership matter? Evidence from local public transport in Europe , 2010 .

[14]  Carlo Giupponi,et al.  Potentials and Limits of Bayesian Networks to Deal with Uncertainty in the Assessment of Climate Change Adaptation Policies , 2010 .

[15]  Alice Favero,et al.  Fairness, Credibility, and Effectiveness in the Copenhagen Accord: An Economic Assessment , 2010 .

[16]  J. Bhagwati,et al.  Is action against US exports for failure to sign Kyoto Protocol WTO-legal? , 2007, World Trade Review.

[17]  D. Smith A statement , 2005, Journal of Religion and Health.

[18]  ZhongXiang Zhang,et al.  Why has China not embraced a global cap-and-trade regime? , 2003 .

[19]  L. Goulder,et al.  When Can Carbon Abatement Policies Increase Welfare? The Fundamental Role of Distorted Factor Markets , 1996 .

[20]  Alice Favero,et al.  Investments and Financial Flows Induced by Climate Mitigation Policies , 2010 .

[21]  Pierre Desprairies,et al.  World Energy Outlook , 1977 .

[22]  Aie World Energy Outlook 2009 , 2000 .

[23]  Georg Umgiesser,et al.  An Economic Assessment of the Impacts of the Mose Barriers on Venice Port Activities , 2010 .

[24]  ZhongXiang Zhang,et al.  Asian Energy and Environmental Policy: Promoting Growth While Preserving the Environment , 2008 .

[25]  F. Bosello Adaptation, Mitigation and 'Green' R&D to Combat Global Climate Change - Insights from an Empirical Integrated Assessment Exercise , 2008 .

[26]  Zhongxiang Zhang Should the rule of allocating emissions permits be harmonised , 1999 .

[27]  Philippe Quirion,et al.  Tackling Leakage in a World of Unequal Carbon Prices Carbon pricing effects on cost structures and trade flows of energy intensive industries , 2008 .

[28]  H. Kee,et al.  International trade and climate change : economic, legal, and institutional perspectives , 2007 .

[29]  Luca Di Corato,et al.  Profit Sharing under the Threat of Nationalization , 2013 .

[30]  M. Tavoni,et al.  The Role of International Carbon Offsets in a Second-Best Climate Policy: A Numerical Evaluation , 2010 .

[31]  Brigitte Stern,et al.  United States Import Prohibition of Certain Shrimp and Shrimp Products , 2006 .

[32]  佐藤 龍三郎,et al.  Selected demographic indicators from the United Nations' world population prospects, the 2008 revision , 2009 .

[33]  M. Moretto,et al.  Licences, 'Use or Lose' Provisions and the Time of Investment , 2010 .

[34]  Juri Marcucci,et al.  'Google It!' Forecasting the US Unemployment Rate with A Google Job Search Index , 2010 .

[35]  ZhongXiang Zhang,et al.  Why Did the Energy Intensity Fall in China's Industrial Sector in the 1990s? The Relative Importance of Structural Change and Intensity Change , 2003 .

[36]  A. Bovenberg,et al.  Addressing Industry-Distributional Concerns in U.S. Climate-Change Policy , 2001 .

[37]  Makoto Okamura,et al.  Optimal Emission Tax with Endogenous Location Choice of Duopolistic Firms , 2009 .

[38]  ZhongXiang Zhang,et al.  Can China afford to commit itself an emissions cap? An economic and political analysis , 2000 .

[39]  E. Geller,et al.  Preserving the environment , 1982 .

[40]  ZhongXiang Zhang,et al.  Domestic Climate Policies and the WTO , 2001 .

[41]  Carlo Carraro,et al.  Modeling Biased Technical Change - Implications for Climate Policy , 2010 .

[42]  Aie World Energy Outlook 2007 , 2007 .

[43]  Xin Wang,et al.  Can Unilateral Trade Measures Significantly Reduce Leakage and Competitiveness Pressures on EU-ETS-Constrained Industries? The Case of China Export Taxes and VAT Rebates , 2009 .

[44]  John Whalley,et al.  Leveling the Carbon Playing Field: International Competition and US Climate Policy Design by Trevor Houser, Rob Bradley, Britt Childs, Jacob Werksman and Robert Heilmayr Washington, DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics, 2008 , 2009, World Trade Review.

[45]  A. Petrucci Second-Best Optimal Taxation of Oil and Capital in a Small Open Economy , 2010 .

[46]  ZhongXiang Zhang,et al.  Open Trade with the U.S. Without Compromising Canada's Ability to Comply with its Kyoto Target , 2003 .

[47]  Kommerskollegium Climate and Trade Rules - harmony or conflict? , 2004 .

[48]  L. Assunção,et al.  Domestic climate policy and the WTO , 2001 .

[49]  Carlo Giupponi,et al.  A Participatory Approach to Assess the Effectiveness of Responses to Cope with Flood Risk , 2010 .

[50]  T. Wälde The International Energy Agency (IEA) , 2003 .