Fortune, Risk, and the Microeconomics of Migration

Publisher Summary This chapter describes the fortune, the risk, and the microeconomics of migration. Fortune is the opportunity present in risk. Hence, howsoever men would comport themselves in the company of risk, their actions must in some part betray fortune's influence. By risk, it refers to the casual element of men's experience, the unreasoning and unforetold ways of the world, the irremovable dispersion in the imaginable assortments of events attending actions taken in ignorance. By fortune, it means the scope left for human judgment and volition where fate does not rule and outcomes are not all predetermined. Fortune represents the element of disorder essential to opportunity, the uncharted paths that afford men the freedom to learn and profit from the mutability of the world. It is fortune that furnishes occasions for the trials and training that are the substance of the human adventure. This usage reflects a thoroughly Renaissance view of the function of the casual element in the universal design, a merging of the traditions of Boethius, St. Thomas, and Dante. The chapter also discusses a model to describe the choice of an optimal single-period strategy of wealth accumulation for a von Neumann–Morgenstern utility-maximizing household, which may allocate as much as a fixed proportion s of its initial wealth to investments in migration and local job search.

[1]  P. Nelson MIGRATION, REAL INCOME AND INFORMATION1 , 1959 .

[2]  Joan V. Robinson,et al.  The Second Crisis of Economic Theory , 1972 .

[3]  K. Arrow,et al.  QUASI-CONCAVE PROGRAMMING , 1961 .

[4]  Richard L. Morrill,et al.  Marriage, Migration, and the Mean Information Field: A Study in Uniqueness and Generality , 1967 .

[5]  G. Stigler The Economics of Information , 1961, Journal of Political Economy.

[6]  J. Q. Stewart Empirical Mathematical Rules concerning the Distribution and Equilibrium of Population , 1947 .

[7]  J. Vanderkamp,et al.  Migration Flows, Their Determinants and the Effects of Return Migration , 1971, Journal of Political Economy.

[8]  P. Nelson Information and Consumer Behavior , 1970, Journal of Political Economy.

[9]  G. Wilber Migration Expectancy in the United States , 1963 .

[10]  John A. Tomaske The Determinants of Intercountry Differences in European Emigration: 1881–1900 , 1971, Journal Economic History.

[11]  Reuben Gronau,et al.  Information and Frictional Unemployment , 1971 .

[12]  J. Tobin Liquidity Preference as Behavior towards Risk , 1958 .

[13]  Dale T. Mortensen,et al.  Job Search, the Duration of Unemployment, and the Phillips Curve: Comment , 1972 .

[14]  E. Ravenstein The Laws of Migration , 1885, Encyclopedia of Gerontology and Population Aging.

[15]  S. Tsiang The Rationale of the Mean-Standard Deviation Analysis, Skewness Preference, and the Demand for Money , 1972 .

[16]  A. Alchian,et al.  INFORMATION COSTS, PRICING, AND RESOURCE UNEMPLOYMENT , 1969 .

[17]  L. Gallaway,et al.  Emigration from the United Kingdom to the United States: 1860–1913 , 1971, The Journal of Economic History.

[18]  George J. Stigler,et al.  Information in the Labor Market , 1962, Journal of Political Economy.

[19]  Richard X. Chase,et al.  Interprovincial Migration in Canada as a Human Capital Decision , 1971, Journal of Political Economy.

[20]  P. J. Mooney,et al.  A Model for the Dispersion of the Migrant Labor Force and Some Results for the United States, 1880-1920 , 1970 .

[21]  Hirschel Kasper,et al.  The Asking Price of Labor and the Duration of Unemployment , 1967 .

[22]  Allen C. Kelley,et al.  International Migration and Economic Growth: Australia, 1865–1935 , 1965 .

[23]  M. Todaro,et al.  A Model for Labor Migration and Urban Unemployment in Less Developed Countries , 1969 .

[24]  J. McCall Economics of Information and Job Search , 1970 .