Strategic Investment in Merchant Transmission: The Impact of Capacity Utilization Rules

In this paper we look at the relative merits of two capacity utilization regimes in the merchant electricity transmission network: Must offer (Mo) where the entire capacity installed has to be made available for transmission and Non Must Offer (NMo) where some capacity could be withheld. We look at two specific cases: (i) demand for transmission varies across time, and (ii) vertical integration is allowed between investors in transmission network and electricity generators. In the case of time-varying demand under Mo, we find that a monopolist may underinvest in transmission when compared to NMo, although NMo may lead to more capacity withholding. In the case of vertical integration, we find that when the market power is with the generators of the exporting node, without vertical integration no welfare-enhancing merchant investment would occur, neither under Mo nor NMo. Further, if the generators in the importing node have market power, in case vertical integration is allowed, Mo is better than NMo. Finally, we also argue that the incentive to collude among various transmission network investors is mitigated with Mo in place.

[1]  J. Bain Barriers to new competition , 1957 .

[2]  Gert Brunekreeft,et al.  Regulatory issues in merchant transmission investment , 2005 .

[3]  John Geanakoplos,et al.  Holding Idle Capacity to Deter Entry [The Role of Investment in Entry Deterrence] , 1985 .

[4]  J. Graves Merchant transmission , 2002, IEEE Power Engineering Society Summer Meeting,.

[5]  Blaise Allaz,et al.  Cournot Competition, Forward Markets and Efficiency , 1993 .

[6]  Gert Brunekreeft,et al.  Should merchant transmission investment be subject to a must-offer provision? , 2006 .

[7]  Steven Stoft,et al.  Financial Transmission Rights Meet Cournot: How TCCs Curb Market Power* , 1999 .

[8]  Stephen C. Peck,et al.  A market mechanism for electric power transmission , 1996 .

[9]  Shmuel S. Oren,et al.  Economic Inefficiency of Passive Transmission Rights in Congested Electricity Systems with Competitive Generation , 1997 .

[10]  R. Weiner,et al.  Markets for Power: An Analysis of Electric Utility Deregulation , 1985 .

[11]  R. Ramos,et al.  Occupational Mobility of Immigrants in a Low Skilled Economy: The Spanish Case , 2010, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[12]  S. Borenstein,et al.  The Competitive Effects of Transmission Capacity in a Deregulated Electricity Industry , 1997 .

[13]  Regulated and merchant interconnectors in Australia: SNI and Murraylink revisited , 2004 .

[14]  C. C. von Weizsaker,et al.  A Welfare Analysis of Barriers to Entry , 1980 .

[15]  Richard Green,et al.  The Electricity Contract Market in England and Wales , 2003 .

[16]  Robert B. Wilson,et al.  Research Paper Series Graduate School of Business Stanford University Architecture of Power Markets Architecture of Power Markets 1 , 2022 .

[17]  R. Deneckere,et al.  Excess Capacity and Collusion , 1990 .

[18]  J. Tirole,et al.  Transmission rights and market power on electric power networks , 1999 .

[19]  B. Nowak Equal access to the energy infrastructure as a precondition to promote competition in the energy market. The case of European Union , 2010 .

[20]  Roger Ware,et al.  A Theory of Market Structure with Sequential Entry , 1987 .

[21]  W. Hogan Contract networks for electric power transmission , 1992 .

[22]  A. Spence Entry, Capacity, Investment and Oligopolistic Pricing , 1977 .

[23]  Felix F. Wu,et al.  Folk theorems on transmission access: Proofs and counterexamples , 1996 .

[24]  Steven Stoft,et al.  Electric grid investment under a contract network regime , 1996 .

[25]  William W. Hogan Transmission Market Design , 2003 .

[26]  James Bushnell,et al.  Transmission Rights and Market Power , 1999 .

[27]  F. Schweppe Spot Pricing of Electricity , 1988 .

[28]  J. Tirole The Theory of Industrial Organization , 1988 .

[29]  Massimo Motta,et al.  Competition Policy: Theory and Practice , 2004 .

[30]  J. Sutton Sunk Costs and Market Structure , 1991 .

[31]  Avinash Dixit,et al.  A MODEL OF DUOPOLY SUGGESTING A THEORY OF ENTRY BARRIERS , 1978 .

[32]  Steven Stoft,et al.  Improving private incentives for electric grid investment , 1997 .

[33]  J. Laffont,et al.  A Theory of Incentives in Procurement and Regulation , 1993 .

[34]  Roger Ware,et al.  Sunk Costs and Strategic Commitment: A Proposed Three-Stage Equilibrium , 1984 .

[35]  Thomas-Olivier Léautier,et al.  Transmission Constraints and Imperfect Markets for Power , 2001 .

[36]  A. Vaglio,et al.  Why Do Educated Mothers Matter? A Model of Parental Help , 2010 .

[37]  Enzo Sauma,et al.  Do generation firms in restructured electricity markets have incentives to support social-welfare-improving transmission investments? , 2009 .

[38]  Jean Tirole,et al.  Reliability and Competitive Electricity Markets , 2004 .

[39]  Felix F. Wu,et al.  Nodal prices and transmission rights: A critical appraisal , 1995 .

[40]  A. Dixit The Role Of Investment In Entry-Deterrence , 1980 .

[41]  Philippe Aghion,et al.  Contracts as a barrier to entry , 1987 .

[42]  Stephen Littlechild,et al.  Transmission regulation, merchant investment, and the experience of SNI and Murraylink in the Australian National Electricity Market , 2003 .

[43]  V. Krishna,et al.  Entry deterrence and dynamic competition: The role of capacity reconsidered , 1991 .

[44]  F. Boffa,et al.  Bottleneck co-ownership as a regulatory alternative , 2008 .

[45]  David M Newbery,et al.  Competition, Contracts, and Entry in the Electricity Spot Market , 1998 .

[46]  Davide Vannoni,et al.  Increasing market interconnection: An analysis of the Italian electricity spot market , 2010 .

[47]  John Vickers,et al.  Competition and Regulation in Vertically Related Markets , 1995 .

[48]  V. Krishna,et al.  RENEGOTIATION IN FINITELY REPEATED GAMES , 1993 .

[49]  Richard J. Gilbert,et al.  Chapter 8 Mobility barriers and the value of incumbency , 1988 .