Resource Use, Institutions, and Sustainability: A Tale of Two Pacific Island Cultures

This paper examines two Pacific Island cultures, Easter Island and Tikopia, and the relationship between natural resource systems, human-made capital, population growth, and institutional change. Easter Island followed a preindustrial society pattern of overshoot-and collapse. However, Tikopia evolved cultural practices leading to zero-population growth and sustainable resource use. Using a modified Lotka- Volterra, predator-prey model, we find (1) investment in human-made capital does not necessarily eliminate the boom- and bust-cycles of economic activity and population observed in many past societies; and (2) institutional adaptation and resource conservation can be critical in achieving population stability.

[1]  Peter A. Victor,et al.  Indicators of sustainable development: some lessons from capital theory , 1991 .

[2]  J. Hartwick,et al.  Intergenerational Equity and the Investment of Rents from Exhaustible Resources in a Two Sector Model , 1977 .

[3]  R. Firth,et al.  The population of Tikopia, 1929 and 1952 , 1957 .

[4]  P. Kirch Microcosmic histories : Island perspectives on global change , 1997 .

[5]  John M. Gowdy,et al.  Limited Wants, Unlimited Means: A Reader On Hunter-Gatherer Economics And The Environment , 1997 .

[6]  D. Pauly,et al.  Fishing down marine food webs , 1998, Science.

[7]  R. Firth The work of the gods in Tikopia ... , 1940 .

[8]  J. Hartwick Investing returns from depleting renewable resource stocks and intergenerational equity , 1978 .

[9]  A. J. Lotka,et al.  Elements of Physical Biology. , 1925, Nature.

[10]  Van Tilburg,et al.  Easter Island: Archaeology, Ecology and Culture , 1994 .

[11]  John C. V. Pezzey,et al.  Economic analysis of sustainable growth and sustainable development , 1989 .

[12]  R. Solow,et al.  Intergenerational Equity and Exhaustable Resources , 1973 .

[13]  P. Vitousek The Hawaiian Islands as a Model System for Ecosystem Studies , 1995 .

[14]  J. Flenley,et al.  Easter Island, Earth Island , 1992 .

[15]  John M. Gowdy,et al.  The Physical Destruction of Nauru: An Example of Weak Sustainability , 1999 .

[16]  L. Zsolnai Limited Wants, Unlimited Means , 1999 .

[17]  A. J. Lotka Elements of Physical Biology. , 1925, Nature.

[18]  Charles Perrings,et al.  Towards an ecological economics of sustainability , 1992 .

[19]  C. Tisdell Sustainability and Sustainable Development: Are These Concepts a Help or a Hindrance to Economics? , 1994 .

[20]  David I. Stern,et al.  The Capital Theory Approach to Sustainability: A Critical Appraisal , 1997 .

[21]  V. Smith The Primitive Hunter Culture, Pleistocene Extinction, and the Rise of Agriculture , 1975, Journal of Political Economy.

[22]  T. Hunt,et al.  Historical ecology in the Pacific Islands : prehistoric environmental and landscape change , 1998 .

[23]  S. Lele Sustainable development: A critical review , 1991 .

[24]  G. F. Vaughn Sustainability and Policy: Limits to Economics , 1995 .

[25]  J. Brander,et al.  The Simple Economics of Easter Island: A Ricardo-Malthus Model of Renewable Resource Use , 1998 .

[26]  Raymond Firth,et al.  We, the Tikopia , 1957 .

[27]  R. Norgaard Sustainability as intergenerational equity : the challenge to economic thought and practice , 1991 .

[28]  Vito Volterra,et al.  Leçons sur la théorie mathématique de la lutte pour la vie , 1931 .

[29]  J. Flenley,et al.  A Radiocarbon Chronology for Human-Induced Environmental Change on Mangaia, Southern Cook Islands, Polynesia , 1991, Radiocarbon.

[30]  D. Bromley Entitlements, missing markets, and environmental uncertainty: Reply , 1991 .

[31]  Colin W. Clark,et al.  Mathematical Bioeconomics: The Optimal Management of Renewable Resources. , 1993 .

[32]  N. Georgescu-Roegen Energy and Economic Myths , 1975 .