Moral Hazard in Health Insurance: How Important is Forward Looking Behavior?

We investigate whether individuals exhibit forward looking behavior in their response to the non-linear pricing common in health insurance contracts. Our empirical strategy exploits the fact that employees who join an employer-provided health insurance plan later in the calendar year face the same initial ("spot") price of medical care but a higher expected end-of-year ("future") price than employees who join the same plan earlier in the year. Our results reject the null of completely myopic behavior; medical utilization appears to respond to the future price, with a statistically significant elasticity of medical utilization with respect to the future price of -0.4 to -0.6. To try to quantify the extent of forward looking behavior, we develop a stylized dynamic model of individual behavior and calibrate it using our estimated behavioral response and additional data from the RAND Health Insurance Experiment. Our calibration suggests that the elasticity estimate may be substantially smaller than the one implied by fully forward-looking behavior, yet it is sufficiently high to have an economically significant effect on the response of annual medical utilization to a non-linear health insurance contract. Overall, our results point to the empirical importance of accounting for dynamic incentives in analyses of the impact of health insurance on medical utilization.

[1]  E. Keeler,et al.  Health insurance and the demand for medical care: evidence from a randomized experiment. , 1987, The American economic review.

[2]  Jonathan Gruber,et al.  Health Insurance Eligibility, Utilization of Medical Care, and Child Health , 1995 .

[3]  Emmanuel Saez,et al.  Do Taxpayers Bunch at Kink Points? , 1999 .

[4]  Eric French,et al.  On the Distribution and Dynamics of Health Costs , 2002 .

[5]  A. Chandra,et al.  Patient Cost-Sharing, Hospitalization Offsets, and the Design of Optimal Health Insurance for the Elderly , 2007 .

[6]  C. Normand,et al.  Free for All: Lessons from the RAND Health Insurance Experiment , 1994 .

[7]  Censored Quantile Instrumental Variable Estimates of the Price Elasticity of Expenditure on Medical Care , 2009 .

[8]  Amy N. Finkelstein The Aggregate Effects of Health Insurance: Evidence from the Introduction of Medicare , 2007 .

[9]  Koichiro Ito,et al.  Do Consumers Respond to Marginal or Average Price? Evidence from Nonlinear Electricity Pricing , 2012 .

[10]  E B Keeler,et al.  The demand for episodes of treatment in the Health Insurance Experiment. , 1988, Journal of health economics.

[11]  I Hendel,et al.  Asymmetric information in health insurance: evidence from the National Medical Expenditure Survey. , 2001, The Rand journal of economics.

[12]  Joseph P. Newhouse,et al.  Deductibles and the Demand for Medical Services: The Theory of the Consumer Facing a Variable Price Schedule Under Uncertainty , 1977 .

[13]  Cut Quarterly Chetty, Raj, and Emmanuel Saez. , 2003 .

[14]  Matthew J. Eichner,et al.  Medical expenditures and major risk health insurance , 1997 .

[15]  Gerard J. van den Berg,et al.  Duration models: specification, identification and multiple durations , 2000 .

[16]  Stephen P. Ryan,et al.  Selection on Moral Hazard in Health Insurance , 2011, The American economic review.

[17]  W. Manning,et al.  Moral Hazard and Consumer Incentives in Health Care , 2000 .

[18]  S. Borenstein CSEM WP 195 To What Electricity Price Do Consumers Respond? Residential Demand Elasticity Under Increasing-Block Pricing , 2022 .

[19]  R. Blundell,et al.  Labor Supply: A Review of Alternative Approaches , 1998 .

[20]  Emmanuel Saez,et al.  Teaching the Tax Code: Earnings Responses to an Experiment with EITC Recipients , 2009 .

[21]  Matthew J. Eichner,et al.  The Demand for Medical Care: What People Pay Does Matter , 1998 .

[22]  Matthew J. Notowidigdo,et al.  Health Insurance and the Consumer Bankruptcy Decision: Evidence from Expansions of Medicaid , 2011 .

[23]  J. Hausman,et al.  The Effect of Taxation on Labor Supply: Evaluating the Gary Negative Income Tax Experiment , 1978, Journal of Political Economy.

[24]  Erzo F. P. Luttmer,et al.  Would People Behave Differently If They Better Understood Social Security? Evidence from a Field Experiment , 2011 .

[25]  B. Handel,et al.  Adverse Selection and Switching Costs in Health Insurance Markets: When Nudging Hurts , 2011 .

[26]  Naomi E. Feldman,et al.  Should the Average Tax Rate Be Marginalized , 2006 .

[27]  Eric French,et al.  On the distribution and dynamics of health care costs , 2004 .

[28]  J. Chevalier,et al.  Are Durable Goods Consumers Forward Looking? Evidence from College Textbooks , 2005 .

[29]  Carl F. Mela,et al.  Determining Consumers’ Discount Rates with Field Studies , 2012 .

[30]  Randall P. Ellis,et al.  Rational behavior in the presence of coverage ceilings and deductibles , 1986 .

[31]  Raj Chetty,et al.  Adjustment Costs, Firm Responses, and Micro vs. Macro Labor Supply Elasticities: Evidence from Danish Tax Records. , 2011, The quarterly journal of economics.

[32]  WHAT GOOD IS WEALTH WITHOUT HEALTH? THE EFFECT OF HEALTH ON THE MARGINAL UTILITY OF CONSUMPTION , 2013 .

[33]  Whitney K. Newey,et al.  Specification tests for distributional assumptions in the tobit model , 1987 .

[34]  J. Hausman The Econometrics of Nonlinear Budget Sets , 1985, Annual Review of Economics.

[35]  J. Newhouse Free for All?: Lessons from the RAND Health Insurance Experiment , 1993 .