Are There Real Effects of Licensing on Academic Research? A Life Cycle View

Whether financial returns to university licensing divert faculty from basic research is examined in a life cycle context. As in traditional life cycle models, faculty devote more time to research, which can be either basic or applied, early and more time to leisure as they age. Licensing has real effects by increasing the ratio of applied to basic effort and reducing leisure throughout the life cycle, but basic research need not suffer. When applied effort adds nothing to the stock of knowledge, licensing reduces research output, but if applied effort leads to publishable output as well as licenses, then research output and the stock of knowledge are higher with licensing than without. When tenure is added to the system, licensing has a positive effect on research output except when the incentives to license are very high.

[1]  Partha Dasgupta,et al.  Information Disclosure and the Economics of Science and Technology , 1987 .

[2]  Michael R. Darby,et al.  GEOGRAPHICALLY LOCALIZED KNOWLEDGE: SPILLOVERS OR MARKETS? , 1998 .

[3]  R. Merton Priorities in scientific discovery: A chapter in the sociology of science. , 1957 .

[4]  E. Mansfield Academic Research Underlying Industrial Innovations , 1995 .

[5]  Marie C. Thursby,et al.  University Licensing and the Bayh-Dole Act , 2003, Science.

[6]  P. David,et al.  Toward a new economics of science , 1994 .

[7]  Fiona E. Murray Innovation as co-evolution of scientific and technological networks: exploring tissue engineering , 2002 .

[8]  Marie C. Thursby,et al.  Disclosure and licensing of University inventions: 'The best we can do with the s**t we get to work with' , 2003 .

[9]  M. Brewer,et al.  Intellectual Capital and the Birth of U.S. Biotechnology Enterprises , 1994 .

[10]  Mark R. Killingsworth,et al.  "Learning by Doing" and "Investment in Training": A Synthesis of Two "Rival" Models of the Life Cycle , 1982 .

[11]  Rosalyn Stewart,et al.  Objectives , 1954, 2021 23rd International Conference on Advanced Communication Technology (ICACT).

[12]  Anne W. Fuller,et al.  Us Faculty Patenting: Inside and Outside the University , 2007 .

[13]  E. Maskin,et al.  The Simple Economics of Research Portfolios , 1987 .

[14]  A. Siow,et al.  Tenure and Other Unusual Personnel Practices in Academia , 1998 .

[15]  Paula E. Stephan,et al.  Property rights and entrepreneurship in science , 1996 .

[16]  J. McDowell,et al.  Obsolescence of Knowledge and Career Publication Profiles: Some Evidence of Differences among Fields in Costs of Interrupted Careers , 1982 .

[17]  Scott Stern,et al.  Disclosure or Secrecy? The Economics of Open Science , 2007 .

[18]  John Beath,et al.  Optimal Incentives for Income-Generation within Universities , 2000 .

[19]  Marie C. Thursby,et al.  Gender Patterns of Research and Licensing Activity of Science and Engineering Faculty , 2005 .

[20]  Norman Kaplan,et al.  The Sociology of Science: Theoretical and Empirical Investigations , 1974 .

[21]  James D. Adams,et al.  Fundamental Stocks of Knowledge and Productivity Growth , 1990, Journal of Political Economy.

[22]  Incentives, Performance, and Academic Tenure , 2005 .

[23]  W. Hagstrom The scientific community , 1966 .

[24]  T. Kuhn,et al.  The Structure of Scientific Revolutions. , 1964 .

[25]  Edward P. Lazear,et al.  The Peter Principle: A Theory of Decline , 2003, Journal of Political Economy.

[26]  H. Carmichael Incentives in Academics: Why is There Tenure? , 1988, Journal of Political Economy.

[27]  A. Siow,et al.  Occupational Choice under Uncertainty , 1984 .

[28]  J. Hicks,et al.  The economics of science , 1996 .

[29]  Gordon C. Winston,et al.  The economics of academic tenure: A relational perspective , 1983 .

[30]  Mildred K Cho,et al.  Financial Conflict‐of‐Interest Policies in Clinical Research: Issues for Clinical Investigators , 2003, Academic medicine : journal of the Association of American Medical Colleges.

[31]  Daniel S. Hamermesh,et al.  Aging and Productivity Among Economists , 1998, Review of Economics and Statistics.

[32]  Marie C. Thursby,et al.  Who is Selling the Ivory Tower , 2000 .

[33]  G. R. Feiwel Arrow and the ascent of modern economic theory , 1987 .

[34]  Philippe Aghion,et al.  Academic Freedom, Private-Sector Focus, and the Process of Innovation , 2005 .

[35]  Marie C. Thursby,et al.  Proofs and Prototypes for Sale: The Licensing of University Inventions , 2001 .

[36]  David C. Mowery,et al.  Technology and the Wealth of Nations , 1992 .

[37]  D. Ulph,et al.  Optimal incentives for income-generation in universities: the rule of thumb for the Compton tax , 2003 .

[38]  R. Nelson,et al.  American Universities and Technical Advance in Industry , 1994 .

[39]  Marie C. Thursby,et al.  Objectives, Characteristics and Outcomes of University Licensing: A Survey of Major U.S. Universities , 2001 .

[40]  Richard Florida,et al.  Industrializing Knowledge: University-Industry Linkages in Japan and the United States , 1999 .

[41]  Paula E. Stephan,et al.  Striking the Mother Lode in Science: The Importance of Age, Place, and Time. , 1993 .

[42]  Arvids A. Ziedonis,et al.  Academic patent quality and quantity before and after the Bayh-Dole act in the United States , 2002 .

[43]  Paula E. Stephan,et al.  Research Productivity over the Life Cycle: Evidence for Academic Scientists , 1991 .

[44]  Paula E. Stephan,et al.  WHO'S PATENTING IN THE UNIVERSITY? EVIDENCE FROM THE SURVEY OF DOCTORATE RECIPIENTS , 2007 .

[45]  F. Stafford,et al.  Labor, Leisure and Training over the Life Cycle , 1976 .