Productivity Differences

Many technologies used by the LDCs are developed in the OECD economies, and as such are designed to make optimal use of the skills of these richer countries' workforces. Due to differences in the supply of skills, some of the tasks performed by skilled workers in the OECD economies will be carried out by unskilled workers in the LDCs. Since the technologies in these tasks are designed to be used by skilled workers, productivity in the LDCs will be low. Even when all countries have equal access to new technologies, this mismatch between skills and technology can lead to sizable differences in total factor productivity and output per worker. Our theory also suggests that productivity differences should be highest in medium-tech sectors, and that the trade regime and the degree of intellectual property right enforcement in the LDCs have an important effect on the direction of technical change and on productivity differences.

[1]  R. Vernon International investment and international trade in the product cycle , 1966 .

[2]  P. Romer Idea gaps and object gaps in economic development , 1993 .

[3]  P. Romer Endogenous Technological Change , 1989, Journal of Political Economy.

[4]  Jess Benhabib,et al.  The role of human capital in economic development Evidence from aggregate cross-country data , 1994 .

[5]  D. Acemoglu Why Do New Technologies Complement Skills? Directed Technical Change and Wage Inequality , 1998 .

[6]  A. Wood,et al.  North-South Trade, Employment and Inequality: Changing Fortunes in a Skill-Driven World , 1994 .

[7]  Susanto Basu,et al.  Appropriate Technology and Growth , 1996 .

[8]  Robert E. Evenson,et al.  Technological change and technology strategy , 1994 .

[9]  Ward Morehouse,et al.  Manufacturing problems in India : the Cummins diesel experience , 1969 .

[10]  C. I. Jones,et al.  Economic growth and the relative price of capital , 1994 .

[11]  Daron Acemoglu Patterns of Skill Premia , 1999 .

[12]  Peter J. Klenow,et al.  Does Schooling Cause Growth or the Other Way Around? , 1998 .

[13]  P. Romer,et al.  Economic Integration and Endogenous Growth , 1990 .

[14]  Edward C. Prescott,et al.  Needed: a theory of total factor productivity , 1998 .

[15]  Deborah Ainger,et al.  Technology and Underdevelopment , 1978 .

[16]  R. Barro,et al.  International Comparisons of Educational Attainment , 1993 .

[17]  A. Atkinson,et al.  A New View of Technological Change , 1969 .

[18]  Z. Griliches,et al.  Changes in the Demand for Skilled Labor within U.S. Manufacturing Industries: Evidence from the Annual Survey of Manufacturing , 1993 .

[19]  R. Summers,et al.  The Penn World Table (Mark 5): An Expanded Set of International Comparisons, 1950-1987 , 1991 .

[20]  Alwyn Young,et al.  Learning by Doing and the Dynamic Effects of International Trade , 1991 .

[21]  J. Bound,et al.  IMPLICATIONS OF SKILL-BIASED TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE: INTERNATIONAL EVIDENCE* ELI BERMAN , 1998 .

[22]  D. Weil,et al.  A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth Author ( s ) : , 2008 .

[23]  Stephen L. Parente,et al.  Barriers to Technology Adoption and Development , 1994, Journal of Political Economy.

[24]  Jonathan Eaton,et al.  International Technology Diffusion: Theory and Measurement , 1999 .

[25]  C. I. Jones,et al.  Why Do Some Countries Produce so Much More Output Per Worker than Others? , 1998 .

[26]  Francesco Caselli,et al.  Reopening the convergence debate: A new look at cross-country growth empirics , 1996 .