Expressing Preferences in a Principal-Agent Task: A Comparison of Choice, Rating, and Matching

One of the more disturbing yet important findings in the social sciences is the observation that alternative tasks result in different expressed preferences among choice alternatives. We examine this problem not from the perspective of an individual making personal decisions, but from the perspective of an agent trying to follow the known values of a principal. In two studies, we train people to evaluate outcomes described by specific attributes and then examine their ability to express these known values with three common tasks: ratings of individual alternatives, choices among triples of alternatives, and matching pairs of alternatives to indifference. We find that each preference assessment method has distinct strengths and weaknesses. Ratings are quick, robust at following known values, and are perceived as an easy task by respondents. However, because ratings require projection to an imprecise response scale, respondents have difficulty when applying them to more complex preference structures. Further, they place too much weight on negative information, a result that is consistent with reference-dependent loss aversion. Choice is perceived as the most realistic task and the one about which people feel the most confident. However, choices exhibit the most negativity, which, in addition to flowing from the same perceptual bias of ratings, may be exacerbated by a screening strategy that excludes alternatives possessing the lowest level of an attribute. Finally, the matching task takes the most time and is perceived to be the most difficult. It shows minimal biases, except for one glaring flaw, a substantial overweighting of the matching variable. This bias is consistent with a well-known compatibility bias and suggests that agents can learn to use a matching task appropriately for all attributes except the matching variable itself. The article concludes with a discussion of the theoretical mechanisms by which these biases infiltrate different elicitation modes and a summary of managerial implications of these results.

[1]  Philippe Delquié,et al.  Bi-Matching: A New Preference Assessment Method to Reduce Compatibility Effects , 1997 .

[2]  Philippe Delquié,et al.  Inconsistent trade-offs between attributes: new evidence in preference assessment biases , 1993 .

[3]  Dan Ariely,et al.  Goal-Based Construction of Preferences: Task Goals and the Prominence Effect , 1999 .

[4]  Kenneth R. Hammond,et al.  Negative effects of outcome-feedback in multiple-cue probability learning. , 1973 .

[5]  A. Tversky,et al.  Contingent weighting in judgment and choice , 1988 .

[6]  Martin Ahlbrecht,et al.  An empirical study on intertemporal decision making under risk , 1997 .

[7]  P. Schmidt,et al.  Limited-Dependent and Qualitative Variables in Econometrics. , 1984 .

[8]  G. W. Fischer,et al.  Strategy compatibility, scale compatibility, and the prominence effect. , 1993 .

[9]  Paul Slovic,et al.  Dimensional Commensurability and Cue Utilization in Comparative Judgment. , 1974 .

[10]  A. Tversky,et al.  Compatibility effects in judgment and choice. , 1990 .

[11]  Christopher K. Hsee,et al.  The Evaluability Hypothesis: An Explanation for Preference Reversals between Joint and Separate Evaluations of Alternatives , 1996 .

[12]  E. E. Jones Attribution: Perceiving the Causes of Behavior , 1987 .

[13]  S. Addelman Orthogonal Main-Effect Plans for Asymmetrical Factorial Experiments , 1962 .

[14]  G. S. Maddala,et al.  Limited-dependent and qualitative variables in econometrics: Bibliography , 1983 .

[15]  P. Slovic The Construction of Preference , 1995 .

[16]  H. J. Einhorn Use of nonlinear, noncompensatory models as a function of task and amount of information , 1971 .

[17]  I. Simonson,et al.  Attribute–Task Compatibility as a Determinant of Consumer Preference Reversals: , 1997 .

[18]  Eric J. Johnson,et al.  Cognitive processes in preference reversals , 1989 .

[19]  Barbara A. Mellers,et al.  Are preference reversals reduced when made explicit , 1995 .

[20]  D. Winterfeldt,et al.  Comparison of weighting judgments in multiattribute utility measurement , 1991 .

[21]  A. Tversky,et al.  Choices, Values, and Frames , 2000 .

[22]  Peter Wright The harassed decision maker: Time pressures, distractions, and the use of evidence. , 1974 .

[23]  Max H. Bazerman,et al.  Reversals of preference in allocation decisions: Judging an alternative versus choosing among alternatives , 1992 .

[24]  Shelley E. Taylor,et al.  Asymmetrical effects of positive and negative events: the mobilization-minimization hypothesis. , 1991, Psychological bulletin.

[25]  Stuart M. Senter,et al.  Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes Looking and Weighting in Judgment and Choice Performed without Ever Forming an Overall Integrated , 2022 .

[26]  Kathryn Kadous,et al.  The Joint Effects of Task-Related Negative Affect and Task Difficulty in Multiattribute Choice , 1997 .

[27]  J. E. Russo,et al.  An Eye-Fixation Analysis of Choice Processes for Consumer Nondurables , 1994 .

[28]  Eric J. Johnson,et al.  A componential analysis of cognitive effort in choice , 1990 .

[29]  Ola Svenson,et al.  Judgment and decision making under time pressure: studies and findings , 1993 .

[30]  H. J. Einhorn The use of nonlinear, noncompensatory models in decision making. , 1970, Psychological bulletin.

[31]  Noreen M. Klein,et al.  An Investigation of Utility-Directed Cutoff Selection , 1987 .

[32]  John W Payne Contingent Decision Behavior: A Review and Discussion of Issues. , 1982 .

[33]  B. Dosher,et al.  Strategies for multiattribute binary choice. , 1983, Journal of experimental psychology. Learning, memory, and cognition.

[34]  David E. Kanouse,et al.  Negativity in evaluations. , 1987 .

[35]  S. Hawkins,et al.  Information Processing Strategies in Riskless Preference Reversals: The Prominence Effect , 1994 .