Incentives, Routines and Self-Command

What is the source of the value added by organization? Two leading explanations are coordination of specialized efforts and control of opportunistic behaviour. Both explanations assume that humans are boundedly rational — unable to process large amounts of information, to foresee all possible events, or to ferret out the facts known by others. In addition, control-of-opportunism theories (which have been dominant of late) assume that individuals are self-seeking and often dishonest. In models assuming opportunism, boundedness is invoked to establish the regime of action; within that regime, individuals behave coolly and strategically up to the limits of their ability, making no systematic errors. In these models, incentives, monitoring, and control procedures are seen as reducing the externality problems among individuals caused by cheating and shirking. In coordination models, organizational procedures are explained as necessary to reduce the probability that cooperating individuals will accidentally interfere with one another, leave vital tasks undone because they each expect someone else to perform them, or ignore information relevant to decisions. Both classes of explanation focus on the problems caused by the need for effective cooperation.

[1]  G. Loewenstein,et al.  Decision making over time and under uncertainty: a common approach , 1991 .

[2]  Bengt Holmstrom,et al.  Moral Hazard and Observability , 1979 .

[3]  T. Schelling Enforcing Rules on Oneself , 1985 .

[4]  I. Fisher,et al.  The theory of interest , 1956 .

[5]  N. Mckendrick II. Josiah Wedgwood and Factory Discipline , 1961, The Historical Journal.

[6]  Walter Schneider,et al.  Controlled and automatic human information processing: II. Perceptual learning, automatic attending and a general theory. , 1977 .

[7]  R J HERRNSTEIN,et al.  Relative and absolute strength of response as a function of frequency of reinforcement. , 1961, Journal of the experimental analysis of behavior.

[8]  R. Thaler Some empirical evidence on dynamic inconsistency , 1981 .

[9]  Jerry A. Hausman,et al.  Individual Discount Rates and the Purchase and Utilization of Energy-Using Durables , 1979 .

[10]  G. Ainslie Specious reward: a behavioral theory of impulsiveness and impulse control. , 1975, Psychological bulletin.

[11]  R. H. Strotz Myopia and Inconsistency in Dynamic Utility Maximization , 1955 .

[12]  R. Thaler,et al.  An Economic Theory of Self-Control , 1977, Journal of Political Economy.

[13]  Herbert A. Simon,et al.  Human Nature in Politics: The Dialogue of Psychology with Political Science , 1985, American Political Science Review.

[14]  Aristotle,et al.  The Works of Aristotle , 1929, Nature.

[15]  Barry Wilkinson,et al.  The Japanization of British industry , 1988 .

[16]  G. Loewenstein,et al.  Anomalies in Intertemporal Choice: Evidence and an Interpretation , 1992 .

[17]  G. Ainslie,et al.  Impulse control in pigeons. , 1974, Journal of the experimental analysis of behavior.

[18]  J. Langton The Ecological Theory of Bureaucracy: The Case of Josiah Wedgwood and the British Pottery Industry , 1984 .

[19]  Peter C. Reid,et al.  Well Made in America: Lessons from Harley-Davidson on Being the Best , 1989 .

[20]  R. Herrnstein,et al.  Melioration: A Theory of Distributed Choice , 1991 .

[21]  U. Ben-Zion,et al.  Discount rates inferred from decisions: an experimental study , 1989 .

[22]  David A. Eckerman,et al.  An experimental analysis of impulsivity and impulse control in humans. , 1980 .

[23]  G. J. Stansfield,et al.  The River and the Gauntlet , 1962 .

[24]  W. James,et al.  The Principles of Psychology. , 1983 .

[25]  N. Rosenberg,et al.  How the West Grew Rich: The Economic Transforma-tion of the Industrial World , 1987 .

[26]  H Rachlin,et al.  Commitment, choice and self-control. , 1972, Journal of the experimental analysis of behavior.

[27]  George A. Akerlof Procrastination and Obedience , 1991 .