Volatility misspecification, option pricing and superreplication via coupling

Consider the performance of an options writer who misspecifies the dynamics of the price process of the underlying asset by overestimating asset price volatility. When does he overprice the option? If he follows the hedging strategy suggested by his model, when does the terminal value of his strategy dominate the option payout? We show that both these events happen if the option payoff is a convex function of the price of the underlying at maturity. The proofs involve the simple, powerful and intuitive techniques of coupling. 1. Robust hedging and superreplication. The standard approach in mathematical finance, and particularly in the pricing of derivative securities, is to begin by writing down a stochastic model, which is assumed, without comment, to correctly and precisely specify the dynamics of the underlying asset. Arbitrage theory, backed by change of measure techniques and martingale representation theorems, then allows options to be priced and hedged. The fairness of the price and the success of the hedge depend crucially on the truth of the underlying model. The purpose of this article is to consider the implications of a misspecification of the dynamics of the asset price process. In particular, if the options writer uses an incorrect model, when does he overcharge for the option? Further, if he attempts to hedge using this incorrect model, can he still replicate (or rather superreplicate) the option payoff? (A superreplicating strategy is a dynamic hedging strategy which generates a terminal wealth which stochastically dominates the option payout.) It is well known that the price of a call option in the Black-Scholes model is an increasing function of the volatility parameter and that this monotonicity property extends to all European options with convex payoff profiles. We generalize this result to prove a price comparison theorem for pairs of models with stochastic volatilities. We have in mind the scenario where one model is used by the options writer to price and hedge options, and the second model represents the (unknown) truth.

[1]  R. Frey,et al.  Bounds on European Option Prices under Stochastic Volatility , 1999 .

[2]  M. Avellaneda,et al.  Pricing and hedging derivative securities in markets with uncertain volatilities , 1995 .

[3]  Rüdiger Frey The Pricing and Hedging of Options in Finitely Elastic Markets , 1996 .

[4]  Rüdiger Frey,et al.  Market Volatility and Feedback Effects from Dynamic Hedging , 1997 .

[5]  T. Lindvall Lectures on the Coupling Method , 1992 .

[6]  S. Shreve,et al.  Robustness of the Black and Scholes Formula , 1998 .

[7]  Optimal hedging strategies for misspecified asset price models , 1999 .

[8]  A. Bensoussan On the theory of option pricing , 1984, Acta Applicandae Mathematicae.

[9]  N. Shephard Statistical aspects of ARCH and stochastic volatility , 1996 .

[10]  Terry Lyons,et al.  Uncertain volatility and the risk-free synthesis of derivatives , 1995 .

[11]  I. Karatzas Optimization problems in the theory of continuous trading , 1989 .

[12]  R. Myneni The Pricing of the American Option , 1992 .

[13]  M. Yor,et al.  Continuous martingales and Brownian motion , 1990 .

[14]  Ioannis Karatzas,et al.  Brownian Motion and Stochastic Calculus , 1987 .

[15]  A. Friedman Partial Differential Equations of Parabolic Type , 1983 .

[16]  David Hobson,et al.  Robust hedging of the lookback option , 1998, Finance Stochastics.

[17]  L. Rogers,et al.  Diffusions, Markov processes, and martingales , 1979 .

[18]  H. Föllmer,et al.  Hedging of contingent claims under incomplete in-formation , 1991 .

[19]  I. Karatzas On the pricing of American options , 1988 .

[20]  P. Protter Stochastic integration and differential equations , 1990 .