Price, private demand and optimal provision of public R&D investment: An application to Italian agriculture, 1960–1995

The current paper presents a model in which public R&D stock is included as a quasi-fixed input in a variable cost function. Its price affects the long run desired level, while its shadow price indicates whether under (over) investment occurs in the short run. Two alternative R&D prices and, thus, two different long-run desired levels, are defined. One concerns the private (farmer) perspective, in which farmers express demand under the assumption of costless R&D. The other considers the societal point of view, in which the objective is the optimal public R&D supply conditioned on its cost. Application of the above model to the Italian agricultural context (1960–1995) suggests a significant difference between these private and social desired R&D levels. The latter are, on average, closer to the observed values, though over-investment has emerged since the mid-eighties.

[1]  M. Paul,et al.  ENDOGENOUS TECHNICAL CHANGE , 1990 .

[2]  Roberto Esposti,et al.  Modelling technical change in Italian agriculture: a latent variable approach , 2000 .

[3]  P. Pardey,et al.  Research returns redux: a meta-analysis of the returns to agricultural R&D , 2000 .

[4]  Michael Aliber,et al.  An Analysis of the Source and Nature of Technical Change: The Case of U.S. Agriculture , 1997, Review of Economics and Statistics.

[5]  P. Romer Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth , 1986, Journal of Political Economy.

[6]  Zvi Griliches,et al.  Comparing Productivity Growth: An Exploration of French and U.S. Industrial and Firm Data , 1982 .

[7]  John W. Kendrick,et al.  New developments in productivity measurement and analysis , 1981 .

[8]  Katharina Wakelin,et al.  Productivity growth and R&D expenditure in UK manufacturing firms , 2001 .

[9]  Zvi Griliches,et al.  Returns to Research and Development Expenditures in the Private Sector , 1998 .

[10]  Theofanis P. Mamuneas,et al.  The Effects of Public Infrastructure and R&D Capital on the Cost Structure and Performance of U.S. Manufacturing Industries , 1991 .

[11]  Edwin Mansfield,et al.  R&D and Innovation: Some Empirical Findings , 1984 .

[12]  D. Harhoff R&D and Productivity in German Manufacturing Firms , 1998 .

[13]  R. Barro Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogeneous Growth , 1988, Journal of Political Economy.

[14]  C. Morrison,et al.  Knowledge Capital and Cost Structure in the U.S. Food and Fiber Industries , 1998 .

[15]  P. Bottomley,et al.  IS PUBLICLY FUNDED AGRICULTURAL RESEARCH EXCESSIVE , 1988 .

[16]  Robert E. Evenson,et al.  R&D Spillovers to Agriculture: Measurement and Application , 1999 .

[17]  Roberto Esposti,et al.  Public R&D Investment and Cost Structure in Italian Agriculture 1960-1995 , 2003 .

[18]  Zvi Griliches,et al.  R&D, Patents, and Productivity , 1981 .

[19]  R. Nehring,et al.  Scale Economies and Efficiency in U.S. Agriculture: Are Traditional Farms History? , 2004 .

[20]  Jean-Paul Chavas,et al.  Applied Production Analysis: A Dual Approach , 1988 .

[21]  Yair Mundlak,et al.  Production and supply , 1998 .

[22]  C. Morrison Quasi-fixed Inputs in U.S. and Japanese Manufacturing: a Generalized Leontief Restricted Cost Function Approach , 1988 .

[23]  P. Pardey,et al.  U.S. agricultural research deflators: 1890–1985 , 1989 .

[24]  P. Bottomley,et al.  The rate of return to public sector agricultural R&D in the UK, 1965–80 , 1989 .

[25]  P. Romer Endogenous Technological Change , 1989, Journal of Political Economy.

[26]  Roberto Esposti,et al.  Public agricultural R&D design and technological spill-ins: A dynamic model , 2002 .

[27]  Charles I. Jones,et al.  R & D-Based Models of Economic Growth , 1995, Journal of Political Economy.

[28]  M. Nadiri,et al.  Innovations and Technological Spillovers , 1993 .

[29]  S. Kumbhakar Productivity and technical change: Measurement and testing , 2004 .

[30]  C. I. Jones,et al.  Too Much of a Good Thing? The Economics of Investment in R&D , 1999 .

[31]  Donald Siegel,et al.  External Capital Factors and Increasing Returns in U.S. Manufacturing , 1997, Review of Economics and Statistics.

[32]  Francesco Aiello,et al.  Il tasso di rendimento degli investimenti in ricerca e sviluppo delle imprese innovatrici italiane , 2004 .

[33]  Ramón López Under‐investing in public goods: evidence, causes, and consequences for agricultural development, equity, and the environment , 2003 .

[34]  Roberto Esposti,et al.  R&D, technology and productivity growth in Italian agriculture, 1963-1991 , 2003 .

[35]  Robert E. Evenson,et al.  Economic impacts of agricultural research and extension , 2001 .

[36]  Roberto Esposti,et al.  The impact of public R&D and extension expenditure on Italian agriculture: an application of a mixed parametric-nonparametric approach , 2000 .

[37]  Edwin Mansfield,et al.  Price indexes for R and D inputs 1969-1983 , 1987 .

[38]  Catherine J. Morrison Paul,et al.  State Infrastructure and Productive Performance , 1992 .

[39]  A. Barnes Towards a framework for justifying public agricultural R&D: the example of UK agricultural research policy , 2001 .

[40]  C. I. Jones,et al.  Measuring the Social Return to R&D , 1997 .

[41]  G. Grossman,et al.  Innovation and growth in the global economy , 1993 .

[42]  R. Barro,et al.  Public Finance in Models of Economic Growth , 1990 .

[43]  Edwin Mansfield,et al.  R&D Price Indexes and Real R&D Expenditures in the United States , 1982 .

[44]  Roberto Esposti,et al.  Building the Knowledge Stock: Lags, Depreciation, and Uncertainty in R&D Investment and Link with Productivity Growth , 2003 .

[45]  Z. Griliches The Search for R&D Spillovers , 1991 .

[46]  I. Prucha,et al.  Estimation of the Depreciation Rate of Physical and R&D Capital in the U.S. Total Manufacturing Sector , 1993 .

[47]  Robert Chambers,et al.  Applied Production Analysis , 1988 .