Temperature , Growth , and Asset Prices

This article makes a contribution towards understanding the impact of temperature fluctuations on the economy and financial markets. Using historical aggregate U.S. data we show that temperature negatively impacts future growth up to 10 years. We present a long-run risks model with temperature related natural disasters. The model simultaneously matches observed temperature and consumption growth dynamics, and key features of financial markets data. We use this model to evaluate the role of temperature in determining asset prices, and to compute utility-based welfare costs as well as dollar costs of insuring against temperature fluctuations. We find that the temperature related utility-costs are about 7% of consumption, and the total dollar costs of completely insuring against temperature variation are about 104% of GDP. We show that the same features, long-run risks and recursive-preferences, that account for the risk-free rate and the equity premium puzzles also imply that temperaturerelated economic costs are high. Our model implies that a rise in global temperature lowers equity valuations and raises risk premiums.

[1]  W. Nordhaus Climate and economic development : climates past and climate change future , 1993 .

[2]  Amir Yaron,et al.  What's Vol Got to Do with It , 2011 .

[3]  Erzo F. P. Luttmer,et al.  NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE DYNAMICS OF CRIMINAL BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM WEATHER SHOCKS , 2022 .

[4]  Benjamin F. Jones,et al.  Temperature and Income: Reconciling New Cross-Sectional and Panel Estimates , 2009 .

[5]  J. Horowitz The Income–Temperature Relationship in a Cross-Section of Countries and its Implications for Predicting the Effects of Global Warming , 2009 .

[6]  Thomas D. Crocker,et al.  Hours of Work, Labor Productivity, and Environmental Conditions: A Case Study , 1981 .

[7]  Tobias N. Rasmussen Macroeconomic Implications of Natural Disasters in the Caribbean , 2004, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[8]  R. Barro Rare Disasters and Asset Markets in the Twentieth Century , 2006 .

[9]  M. Simpson Global Climate Change Impacts in the United States , 2011 .

[10]  S. Field THE EFFECT OF TEMPERATURE ON CRIME , 1992 .

[11]  J. Sachs,et al.  The economic burden of malaria. , 2001, The American journal of tropical medicine and hygiene.

[12]  A. Meyer Economics Of Climate Change , 1995, Nature.

[13]  Ravi Jagannathan,et al.  Implications of Security Market Data for Models of Dynamic Economies , 1990, Journal of Political Economy.

[14]  Ravi Bansal Long-Run Risks and Risk Compensation in Equity Markets , 2008 .

[15]  Ravi Bansal,et al.  Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles , 2000 .

[16]  Chao Shen,et al.  Climate Shocks and Economic Growth : Evidence from the Last Half Century , 2008 .

[17]  M. Weitzman A Review of The Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change , 2007 .

[18]  Robert E. Lucas,et al.  Models of business cycles , 1987 .

[19]  Lars Peter Hansen,et al.  Consumption Strikes Back? Measuring Long‐Run Risk , 2005, Journal of Political Economy.

[20]  Scott L Zeger,et al.  Temperature and mortality in 11 cities of the eastern United States. , 2002, American journal of epidemiology.

[21]  E. Huntington Civilization and Climate , 1916 .

[22]  P. Stott,et al.  Human contribution to the European heatwave of 2003 , 2004, Nature.

[23]  R. Kok,et al.  Effects of Moderate Cold and Heat Stress on Factory Workers in Southern Africa , 1988 .

[24]  R. Mehra,et al.  THE EQUITY PREMIUM A Puzzle , 1985 .

[25]  Ravi Bansal,et al.  A Note on the Economics and Statistics of Predictability : A Long Run Risks Perspective ∗ , 2007 .

[26]  Robert F. Dittmar,et al.  Consumption, Dividends, and the Cross-Section of Equity Returns , 2002 .