Efficient Vote Elicitation under Candidate Uncertainty

Top-k voting is an especially natural form of partial vote elicitation in which only length k prefixes of rankings are elicited. We analyze the ability of top-k vote elicitation to correctly determine true winners, with high probability, given probabilistic models of voter preferences and candidate availability. We provide bounds on the minimal value of k required to determine the correct winner under the plurality and Borda voting rules, considering both worst-case preference profiles and profiles drawn from the impartial culture and Mallows probabilistic models. We also derive conditions under which the special case of zero-elicitation (i.e., k = 0) produces the correct winner. We provide empirical results that confirm the value of top-k voting.

[1]  Vincent Conitzer,et al.  Communication complexity of common voting rules , 2005, EC '05.

[2]  Martin Raab,et al.  "Balls into Bins" - A Simple and Tight Analysis , 1998, RANDOM.

[3]  Jérôme Lang,et al.  Voting procedures with incomplete preferences , 2005 .

[4]  Craig Boutilier,et al.  Robust Winners and Winner Determination Policies under Candidate Uncertainty , 2014, AAAI.

[5]  Meir Kalech,et al.  Practical voting rules with partial information , 2010, Autonomous Agents and Multi-Agent Systems.

[6]  A. A. J. Marley,et al.  Behavioral Social Choice - Probabilistic Models, Statistical Inference, and Applications , 2006 .

[7]  Nicolas de Condorcet Essai Sur L'Application de L'Analyse a la Probabilite Des Decisions Rendues a la Pluralite Des Voix , 2009 .

[8]  Thomas Brendan Murphy,et al.  Mixtures of distance-based models for ranking data , 2003, Comput. Stat. Data Anal..

[9]  J. Marden Analyzing and Modeling Rank Data , 1996 .

[10]  Jörg Rothe,et al.  Anyone but him: The complexity of precluding an alternative , 2005, Artif. Intell..

[11]  Dominique Lepelley Michel Regenwetter, Bernard Grofman, A.A.J. Marley, and Ilia M. Tsetlin: Behavioral social choice. Probabilistic models, statistical inference and applications , 2008, Soc. Choice Welf..

[12]  I. Shevtsova,et al.  On the Upper Bound for the Absolute Constant in the Berry–Esseen Inequality , 2010 .

[13]  Janet Kelly Journal of Economic Perspectives: Summer 1998, Minneapolis , 1999 .

[14]  Vincent Conitzer,et al.  Determining Possible and Necessary Winners under Common Voting Rules Given Partial Orders , 2008, AAAI.

[15]  M. Pollack Journal of Artificial Intelligence Research: Preface , 2001 .

[16]  Abram Bergson,et al.  Social choice and welfare economics under representative government , 1976 .

[17]  Craig Boutilier,et al.  Vote Elicitation with Probabilistic Preference Models: Empirical Estimation and Cost Tradeoffs , 2011, ADT.

[18]  Michael A. Trick,et al.  How hard is it to control an election? Math , 1992 .

[19]  Barteld Kooi,et al.  Proceedings of the Twenty-Second International Joint Conference on Artificial Intelligence (IJCAI-11) , 2011, AAAI 2011.

[20]  K. Pearson Biometrika , 1902, The American Naturalist.

[21]  H. Young Optimal Voting Rules , 1995 .

[22]  Yann Chevaleyre,et al.  Possible Winners when New Candidates Are Added: The Case of Scoring Rules , 2010, AAAI.

[23]  C. L. Mallows NON-NULL RANKING MODELS. I , 1957 .

[24]  Craig Boutilier,et al.  Robust Approximation and Incremental Elicitation in Voting Protocols , 2011, IJCAI.

[25]  Vincent Conitzer,et al.  Eliciting single-peaked preferences using comparison queries , 2007, AAMAS '07.

[26]  Craig Boutilier,et al.  The unavailable candidate model: a decision-theoretic view of social choice , 2010, EC '10.

[27]  Toby Walsh,et al.  How Hard Is It to Control an Election by Breaking Ties? , 2013, ECAI.

[28]  Jerry R. Green,et al.  Assent-maximizing social choice , 2013, Soc. Choice Welf..

[29]  Joachim M. Buhmann,et al.  Cluster analysis of heterogeneous rank data , 2007, ICML '07.

[30]  Anne Lohrli Chapman and Hall , 1985 .

[31]  Craig Boutilier,et al.  Learning Mallows Models with Pairwise Preferences , 2011, ICML.