Good or Bad, We Want it Now: Fixed-Cost Present Bias for Gains and Losses Explains Magnitude Asymmetries in Intertemporal Choice

Intertemporal tradeoffs are ubiquitous in decision making, yet preferences for current versus future losses are rarely explored in empirical research. Whereas rational-economic theory posits that neither outcome sign (gains vs. losses) nor outcome magnitude (small vs. large) should affect delay discount rates, both do, and moreover they interact: while large gains are discounted less than small gains, large losses are discounted more than small losses. This interaction can be understood through a reconceptualization of fixed-cost present bias, which has traditionally described a psychological preference for immediate rewards. First, our results establish present bias for losses, where it describes a psychological preference to have losses over with now. Present bias thus predicts increased discounting of future gains, but decreased (or even negative) discounting of future losses. Second, since present bias feelings do not scale with the magnitude of possible gains or losses, they play a larger role, relative to other motivations for discounting, for small magnitude intertemporal decisions than for large magnitude intertemporal decisions. Present bias thus predicts less discounting of large gains than small gains, but more discounting of large losses than small losses. The present research is the first to demonstrate that the effect of outcome magnitude on discount rates may be opposite for gains and losses, and also the first to offer a theory (extending present bias) and process data to explain this interaction. The results suggest that policy efforts to encourage future-oriented choices should frame outcomes as large gains or small losses.

[1]  H. Rachlin,et al.  The effect of temporal constraints on the value of money and other commodities , 1993 .

[2]  G. Loewenstein,et al.  Time Discounting and Time Preference: A Critical Review , 2002 .

[3]  Noah A. Shamosh,et al.  Individual Differences in Delay Discounting , 2008, Psychological science.

[4]  John G. Lynch,et al.  Resource Slack and Propensity to Discount Delayed Investments of Time Versus Money , 2004, Journal of experimental psychology. General.

[5]  David Laibson,et al.  Individual laboratory-measured discount rates predict field behavior , 2008, Journal of risk and uncertainty.

[6]  George Loewenstein,et al.  Mild opioid deprivation increases the degree that opioid-dependent outpatients discount delayed heroin and money , 2002, Psychopharmacology.

[7]  Temporal Discounting in “Gain Now-Lose Later” and “Lose Now-Gain Later” Conditions , 2007, Psychological reports.

[8]  Stephen J. Hoch,et al.  Time-inconsistent Preferences and Consumer Self-Control , 1991 .

[9]  N. Petry,et al.  Delay discounting of money and alcohol in actively using alcoholics, currently abstinent alcoholics, and controls , 2001, Psychopharmacology.

[10]  R. Thaler,et al.  Anomalies: Intertemporal Choice , 1989 .

[11]  Warren K Bickel,et al.  Congruence of BOLD Response across Intertemporal Choice Conditions: Fictive and Real Money Gains and Losses , 2009, The Journal of Neuroscience.

[12]  Yaacov Trope,et al.  Temporal construal. , 2003, Psychological review.

[13]  Warren K Bickel,et al.  Within-subject comparison of real and hypothetical money rewards in delay discounting. , 2002, Journal of the experimental analysis of behavior.

[14]  K. Kirby,et al.  Modeling Myopic Decisions: Evidence for Hyperbolic Delay-Discounting within Subjects and Amounts , 1995 .

[15]  Ayelet Gneezy,et al.  Procrastination of Enjoyable Experiences , 2010 .

[16]  Suzanne H. Mitchell,et al.  The subjective value of delayed and probabilistic outcomes: Outcome size matters for gains but not for losses , 2010, Behavioural Processes.

[17]  A value function that explains the magnitude and sign effects , 2009 .

[18]  Ran Kivetz,et al.  Self-Control for the Righteous: Toward a Theory of Precommitment to Indulgence , 2002 .

[19]  W. Bickel,et al.  Hypothetical intertemporal choice and real economic behavior: delay discounting predicts voucher redemptions during contingency-management procedures. , 2010, Experimental and clinical psychopharmacology.

[20]  Ted O’Donoghue,et al.  Doing It Now or Later , 1999 .

[21]  D. Goldstein,et al.  Word count: 3998 Corresponding author: , 2022 .

[22]  Toshikazu Hasegawa,et al.  A hyperbolic decay of subjective probability of obtaining delayed rewards , 2007, Behavioral and Brain Functions.

[23]  J. E. Mazur An adjusting procedure for studying delayed reinforcement. , 1987 .

[24]  Brady Reynolds,et al.  Question-based assessments of delay discounting: do respondents spontaneously incorporate uncertainty into their valuations for delayed rewards? , 2007, Addictive behaviors.

[25]  J. Frank Yates,et al.  Preferences for Deferred Losses , 1975 .

[26]  G. Loewenstein Anticipation and the Valuation of Delayed Consumption , 1987 .

[27]  P. Samuelson A Note on Measurement of Utility , 1937 .

[28]  K. Kirby,et al.  Bidding on the Future: Evidence Against Normative Discounting of Delayed Rewards , 1997 .

[29]  David J. Hardisty,et al.  How to Measure Discount Rates? An Experimental Comparison of Three Methods , 2011 .

[30]  K. Kirby,et al.  Delay-discounting probabilistic rewards: Rates decrease as amounts increase , 1996, Psychonomic bulletin & review.

[31]  Ran Kivetz,et al.  Repenting Hyperopia: An Analysis of Self-Control Regrets , 2006 .

[32]  Daniel D. Holt,et al.  Differential effects of amount on temporal and probability discounting of gains and losses , 2006, Memory & cognition.

[33]  Xiuping Li The Effects of Appetitive Stimuli on Out-of-Domain Consumption Impatience , 2008 .

[34]  David J. Hardisty,et al.  Asymmetric discounting of gains and losses: A query theory account , 2011 .

[35]  R. Thaler Some empirical evidence on dynamic inconsistency , 1981 .

[36]  Suzanne B. Shu,et al.  Future‐biased search: the quest for the ideal , 2008 .

[37]  G. Loewenstein,et al.  Anomalies in Intertemporal Choice: Evidence and an Interpretation , 1992 .

[38]  L. Green,et al.  Rate of temporal discounting decreases with amount of reward , 1997, Memory & cognition.

[39]  D. Read,et al.  The Psychology of Intertemporal Tradeoffs , 2009, Psychological review.

[40]  Daniel Read,et al.  DRIFT: an analysis of outcome framing in intertemporal choice. , 2013, Journal of experimental psychology. Learning, memory, and cognition.

[41]  N. Chater,et al.  Associations between a one-shot delay discounting measure and age, income, education and real-world impulsive behavior , 2009 .

[42]  David H. Krantz,et al.  About Time: An Integrative Approach to Effective Environmental Policy , 2012 .

[43]  David J. Hardisty,et al.  Discounting future green: money versus the environment. , 2009, Journal of experimental psychology. General.

[44]  G. Chapman Temporal discounting and utility for health and money. , 1996, Journal of experimental psychology. Learning, memory, and cognition.

[45]  Jess Benhabib,et al.  Present-bias, quasi-hyperbolic discounting, and fixed costs , 2010, Games Econ. Behav..

[46]  David I. Laibson,et al.  Golden Eggs and Hyperbolic Discounting , 1997 .

[47]  Daniel M. Oppenheimer,et al.  Instructional Manipulation Checks: Detecting Satisficing to Increase Statistical Power , 2009 .

[48]  M. Oaksford,et al.  Transactional problem content in cost discounting: parallel effects for probability and delay. , 2011, Journal of experimental psychology. Learning, memory, and cognition.

[49]  L. Warlop,et al.  Bikinis Instigate Generalized Impatience in Intertemporal Choice , 2008 .

[50]  C. Harris Feelings of Dread and Intertemporal Choice , 2012 .

[51]  P. Shrout,et al.  Mediation in experimental and nonexperimental studies: new procedures and recommendations. , 2002, Psychological methods.

[52]  Matthew W. Johnson,et al.  Delay discounting in current and never-before cigarette smokers: similarities and differences across commodity, sign, and magnitude. , 2003, Journal of abnormal psychology.