Vote Buying

We examine the consequences of vote buying, assuming this practice were allowed and free of stigma. Two parties competing in a binary election may purchase votes in a sequential bidding game via up-front binding payments and/or campaign promises (platforms) that are contingent upon the outcome of the election. We analyze the role of the parties’ budget constraints and voter preferences. For instance, if only campaign promises are allowed, then the winning party depends not only on the relative size of the budgets, but also on the excess support of the party with the a priori majority, where the excess support is measured in terms of the (minimal) total utility of supporting voters who are in excess of the majority needed to win. If up front vote buying is permitted, and voters care directly about how they vote (as a legislator would), then the determination of the winning party depends on a weighted comparison of the two parties’ budgets plus half of the total utility of their supporting voters. These results suggest that vote buying can lead to an inefficient party winning in equilibrium. We find that under some circumstances, if parties budgets are raised through donations, then vote buying can be efficient. Finally, we provide some results on vote buying in the face of uncertainty. JEL classification: P16, C72

[1]  Oliver Alfred Gross,et al.  A Continuous Colonel Blotto Game , 1950 .

[2]  James Tobin,et al.  On Limiting the Domain of Inequality , 1970, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[3]  P. Bernholz,et al.  Public Choice , 2018, The Oxford Handbook of Public Choice, Volume 1.

[4]  Sanford J. Grossman,et al.  The free-rider problem and the theory of the corporation , 1980 .

[5]  Mathew D. McCubbins,et al.  Electoral Politics as a Redistributive Game , 1986, The Journal of Politics.

[6]  Vote buying in a stylized setting , 1986 .

[7]  Michael C. Munger,et al.  Legislators and Interest Groups: How Unorganized Interests Get Represented , 1986, American Political Science Review.

[8]  Jstor The journal of economic perspectives , 1987 .

[9]  J. Weibull,et al.  Balanced-budget redistribution as the outcome of political competition , 1987 .

[10]  Oliver Hart,et al.  One Share/One Vote and the Market for Corporate Control , 1987 .

[11]  Artur Raviv,et al.  Corporate control contests and capital structure , 1988 .

[12]  J. Weiss Is vote-selling desirable? , 1988 .

[13]  J. Ferejohn,et al.  Bargaining in Legislatures , 1989, American Political Science Review.

[14]  J. Snyder ON BUYING LEGISLATURES , 1991 .

[15]  R. Myerson Incentives to Cultivate Favored Minorities Under Alternative Electoral Systems , 1993, American Political Science Review.

[16]  Tim Groseclose,et al.  An Examination of the Market for Favors and Votes in Congress , 1996 .

[17]  James M. Snyder,et al.  Equilibrium and efficiency in an organized vote market , 1996 .

[18]  A. Dixit,et al.  The Determinants of Success of Special Interests in Redistributive Politics , 1996, The Journal of Politics.

[19]  Roger B. Myerson,et al.  Bicameralism and Its Consequences for the Internal Organization of Legislatures , 1999 .

[20]  Alessandro Lizzeri,et al.  The provision of public goods under alternative electoral incentives , 2001 .

[21]  Jean-François Laslier,et al.  Distributive Politics and Electoral Competition , 2002, J. Econ. Theory.

[22]  R. Thaler,et al.  Anomalies: The Law of One Price in Financial Markets , 2003 .

[23]  Stephen Ansolabehere,et al.  Why is There so Little Money in Politics , 2003 .

[24]  Balázs Szentes,et al.  Beyond chopsticks: Symmetric equilibria in majority auction games , 2003, Games Econ. Behav..