Weighted scoring elections: is Borda best?

Weighted scoring rules, perhaps the most common procedures for multi-candidate, single-winner elections, are defined by score vectors, of which the Borda Count is the best known example. The concept of Borda dominance identifies candidates who cannot win under any score vector; we assess its usefulness in the context of single-winner elections. We propose several families of score vectors that can accommodate any number of candidates, asking whether any of them can improve on Borda Count. Using large-scale simulation, we compare score vectors on Condorcet efficiency, or ability to find a Condorcet winner when one exists, on resilience to ballot truncation, and on ability to maximize the Copeland score using both complete and uniformly truncated ballots. Borda performs well on criteria related to Condorcet winner and Copeland score but, depending on the preference model, may not be optimal. Convex score vectors are the most resilient to ballot truncation.

[1]  Dominique Lepelley,et al.  On the probability of electing the Condorcet , 1993 .

[2]  Meir Kalech,et al.  Practical voting rules with partial information , 2010, Autonomous Agents and Multi-Agent Systems.

[3]  D. Saari Explaining All Three-Alternative Voting Outcomes , 1999 .

[4]  Matthias Bentert,et al.  Comparing Election Methods Where Each Voter Ranks Only Few Candidates , 2019, AAAI.

[5]  William S. Zwicker,et al.  Which Scoring Rule Maximizes Condorcet Efficiency Under Iac? , 2005 .

[6]  Bernard Grofman,et al.  The Borda Count and its real-world alternatives: Comparing scoring rules in Nauru and Slovenia , 2014 .

[7]  H. Margolis Probability of a tie election , 1977 .

[8]  Donald G. Saari,et al.  Likelihood of voting outcomes with generalized IAC probabilities , 2017, Math. Soc. Sci..

[9]  Jill Van Newenhizen The Borda method is most likely to respect the Condorcet principle , 1992 .

[10]  Peter Emerson,et al.  The original Borda count and partial voting , 2013, Soc. Choice Welf..

[11]  Sarah Wolff,et al.  Generalized Condorcet winners , 2014, Soc. Choice Welf..

[12]  Peter C. Fishburn,et al.  Inverted orders for monotone scoring rules , 1981, Discret. Appl. Math..

[13]  Toby Walsh,et al.  The Computational Impact of Partial Votes on Strategic Voting , 2014, ECAI.

[14]  Bernard De Baets,et al.  A correspondence between voting procedures and stochastic orderings , 2020, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[15]  Jérôme Lang,et al.  Single Transferable Vote: Incomplete Knowledge and Communication Issues , 2019, AAMAS.

[16]  Angèle M. Foley,et al.  The prevalence and consequences of ballot truncation in ranked-choice elections , 2020, Public Choice.

[17]  Martin Lackner Incomplete Preferences in Single-Peaked Electorates , 2014, AAAI.

[18]  Donald G. Saari,et al.  The ultimate of chaos resulting from weighted voting systems , 1984 .

[19]  D. Saari Basic Geometry of Voting , 1995 .

[20]  P. Fishburn Paradoxes of Voting , 1974, American Political Science Review.

[21]  Yuval Filmus,et al.  Efficient voting via the top-k elicitation scheme: a probabilistic approach , 2014, EC.

[22]  Samuel K. Hsiao,et al.  A Borda count for partially ordered ballots , 2014, Soc. Choice Welf..

[23]  Raúl Pérez-Fernández,et al.  The superdominance relation, the positional winner, and more missing links between Borda and Condorcet , 2019 .

[24]  Craig Boutilier,et al.  Efficient Vote Elicitation under Candidate Uncertainty , 2013, IJCAI.

[25]  More Borda Count Variations for Project Assesment , 2008 .

[26]  Donald G. Saari,et al.  Mathematical structure of voting paradoxes , 2000 .

[27]  Manel Ayadi,et al.  Approximating Voting Rules from Truncated Ballots , 2020, EUMAS/AT.

[28]  Onur Doğan,et al.  Implementing the Borda outcome via truncated scoring rules: a computational study , 2012, Public Choice.

[29]  Fabrice Valognes,et al.  On the probability that all decision rules select the same winner , 2000 .

[30]  Georges-Théodule Guilbaud Les théories de l'intérêt général et le problème logique de l'agrégation , 2012 .

[31]  Akimichi Takemura,et al.  Arrangements and Ranking Patterns , 2006 .

[32]  D. Black The theory of committees and elections , 1959 .

[33]  Thierry Marchant The probability of ties with scoring methods: Some results , 2001, Soc. Choice Welf..

[34]  Jean-Pierre Benoit Scoring reversals: a major league dilemma , 1992 .

[35]  William E. Stein,et al.  A stochastic dominance analysis of ranked voting systems with scoring , 1994 .

[36]  Peter C. Fishburn,et al.  Coincidence probabilities for simple majority and positional voting rules , 1978 .

[37]  William V. Gehrlein Weighted Scoring Rules That Maximize Condorcet Efficiency , 2003 .

[38]  Donald G. Saari Millions of election outcomes from a single profile , 1992 .

[39]  B. Llamazares,et al.  Scoring rules and social choice properties: some characterizations , 2015 .

[40]  Steven J. Brams,et al.  The AMS Nomination Procedure Is Vulnerable to ‘Truncation of Preferences’ , 1982 .

[41]  Bonifacio Llamazares,et al.  Positional Voting Systems Generated by Cumulative Standings Functions , 2015 .

[42]  P. Fishburn,et al.  Condorcet's paradox and anonymous preference profiles , 1976 .

[43]  Donald G. Saari,et al.  Connecting pairwise and positional election outcomes , 2013, Math. Soc. Sci..

[44]  Peter C. Fishburn,et al.  Paradoxes of Preferential Voting , 1983 .

[45]  Peter C. Fishburn,et al.  Decision And Value Theory , 1965 .

[46]  B. Reilly Social Choice in the South Seas: Electoral Innovation and the Borda Count in the Pacific Island Countries , 2002 .