Maximizing political efficiency via electoral cycles: An optimal control model

Abstract The exchange between an elected politician, such as a president, prime minister or a local governor and interest groups is analyzed as an optimization problem. The optimal control model shows the conditions required from regulatory policy and resource investment in order to maximize the politician's utility from the interest group's support. Given one interest group, such a policy includes two time intervals: Well in advance of the elections the politician in office should invest a constant level of resources, while for a certain period close to the elections the politician increases or decreases investment, depending on the electoral significance of that interest group. This proves that electoral cycles not only empirically exist, but also maximize the politician's utility from interest groups' support. Given several interest groups, at each point in time, the politician should invest in the group that contribute the most for his or her political interests.

[1]  R. Barro The control of politicians: An economic model , 1973 .

[2]  E. Tower,et al.  The textile bill of 1985: The determinants of congressional voting patterns , 1987 .

[3]  Paul H. Rubin,et al.  Congressman, Constituents, and Contributors , 1982 .

[4]  R. Tollison,et al.  ECONOMIC REGULATION IN MERCANTILE EENGLAND: HECKSCHER REVISITED , 1980 .

[5]  Stephen Morris,et al.  On the Form of Transfers to Special Interests , 1995, Journal of Political Economy.

[6]  D. Hibbs The political economy of industrial democracies , 1987 .

[7]  Elhanan Helpman,et al.  Electoral Competition and Special Interest Politics , 1994 .

[8]  R. Vidal Dynamic optimization: The calculus of variations and optimal control in economics and management: Morton I. KAMIEN and Nancy L. SCHWARTZ Volume 4 in: Dynamic Economics: Theory and Applications, North-Holland, New York, 1981, xi + 331 pages, Dfl.90.00 , 1982 .

[9]  Nathaniel N. Beck Domestic Political Sources of American Monetary Policy: 1955-82 , 1984, The Journal of Politics.

[10]  G. Stigler,et al.  What Can Regulators Regulate? The Case of Electricity , 1962, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[11]  Randolph Sloof,et al.  Interest groups: A survey of empirical models that try to assess their influence , 1996 .

[12]  S. Peltzman Toward a More General Theory of Regulation , 1976, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[13]  S. Lohmann Information, access, and contributions: A signaling model of lobbying , 1995 .

[14]  T. L. Schwartz The Logic of Collective Action , 1986 .

[15]  Michael Boss Economic theory of democracy , 1974 .

[16]  Michael C. Munger,et al.  Economic Models of Interest Groups: An Introductory Survey , 1991 .

[17]  Douglas A. Hibbs,et al.  Political Parties and Macroeconomic Policy , 1977, American Political Science Review.

[18]  M. Olson,et al.  The Logic of Collective Action , 1965 .

[19]  Nathaniel N. Beck Parties, Administrations, and American Macroeconomic Outcomes , 1982, American Political Science Review.

[20]  A. Alesina Macroeconomic Policy in a Two-Party System as a Repeated Game , 1987 .

[21]  Gary S. Becker,et al.  Public Policies, Pressure Groups, and Dead Weight Costs , 1985 .

[22]  W. Nordhaus The Political Business Cycle , 1975 .

[23]  A. C. Chiang Elements of Dynamic Optimization , 1992 .

[24]  M. Petit Dynamic optimization. The calculus of variations and optimal control in economics and management : by Morton I. Kamien and Nancy L. Schwartz. Second Edition. North-Holland (Advanced Textbooks in Economics), Amsterdam and New York, 1991. Pp. xvii+377. ISBN0-444- 01609-0 , 1994 .

[25]  P. Aldhous Taxation or regulation? , 1990, Nature.

[26]  Stuart S. Nagel,et al.  Encyclopedia of Policy Studies , 2020 .