The role of affect in the WTA/WTP disparity

Four studies demonstrated robust within- and between-subject differences in willingness-to-pay (WTP) and willingness-to-accept (WTA) measures of the value of lottery tickets. Buyers and sellers attended to different numerical cues and interpreted the same numbers differently when setting these two kinds of monetary values. Affective influences appeared to guide the valuation process. Buyers with stronger positive feelings about owning a ticket were willing to pay more for a ticket; sellers with stronger negative feelings about no longer having a ticket required a greater minimum payment in exchange for their ticket. In addition, the WTA/WTP disparity tended to be greater for more affectively-laden lottery tickets. The results suggest that WTA and WTP prices are constructed using salient numerical cues and affective feelings. Copyright © 2003 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.

[1]  P. Slovic,et al.  Relative importance of probabilities and payoffs in risk taking , 1968 .

[2]  J. Cacioppo,et al.  Relationship between attitudes and evaluative space: A critical review, with emphasis on the separability of positive and negative substrates. , 1994 .

[3]  Christopher K. Hsee,et al.  Money, Kisses, and Electric Shocks: On the Affective Psychology of Risk , 2001, Psychological science.

[4]  John W. Payne,et al.  Measuring Constructed Preferences: Towards a Building Code , 1999 .

[5]  G. Chapman Similarity and reluctance to trade , 1998 .

[6]  B. Fischhoff,et al.  Rating the Risks , 1979 .

[7]  G. Saucier Mini-markers: a brief version of Goldberg's unipolar big-five markers. , 1994, Journal of personality assessment.

[8]  A. Tversky,et al.  Prospect theory: analysis of decision under risk , 1979 .

[9]  M. Degroot,et al.  Measuring utility by a single-response sequential method. , 1964, Behavioral science.

[10]  Eric J. Johnson,et al.  Framing, probability distortions, and insurance decisions , 1993 .

[11]  D. Ariely,et al.  “Coherent Arbitrariness”: Stable Demand Curves Without Stable Preferences , 2003 .

[12]  Thomas Gilovich,et al.  Just Going Along: Nonconscious Priming and Conformity to Social Pressure , 1999 .

[13]  Paul Slovic,et al.  The Springs of Action: Affective and Analytical Information Processing in Choice , 2000 .

[14]  P. Slovic,et al.  The affect heuristic , 2007, European Journal of Operational Research.

[15]  Cass R. Sunstein,et al.  Shared Outrage and Erratic Awards: The Psychology of Punitive Damages , 1998 .

[16]  G. Clore,et al.  Mood, misattribution, and judgments of well-being: Informative and directive functions of affective states. , 1983 .

[17]  M. F. Luce,et al.  Emotional Trade-Off Difficulty and Choice: , 1999 .

[18]  G. Tom,et al.  The Role of Overt Head Movement in the Formation of Affect , 1991 .

[19]  G. Loewenstein,et al.  Source dependence in the valuation of objects , 1994 .

[20]  A. Tversky,et al.  Prospect Theory : An Analysis of Decision under Risk Author ( s ) : , 2007 .

[21]  Robert D. Willig,et al.  Consumer's Surplus Without Apology , 1976 .

[22]  R. Gregory,et al.  The Role of Past States in Determining Reference Points for Policy Decisions , 1993 .

[23]  Christopher K. Hsee Less is Better: When Low-Value Options are Valued More Highly than High-Value Options , 1998 .

[24]  P. Slovic Differential effects of real versus hypothetical payoffs on choices among gambles. , 1969 .

[25]  D. Ariely,et al.  Focusing on the Forgone: How Value Can Appear So Different to Buyers and Sellers , 2000 .

[26]  G. Loewenstein Out of control: Visceral influences on behavior , 1996 .

[27]  Julie R. Irwin,et al.  Buying/Selling Price Preference Reversals: Preference for Environmental Changes in Buying Versus Selling Modes , 1994 .

[28]  D. Kahneman,et al.  Experimental Tests of the Endowment Effect and the Coase Theorem , 1990, Journal of Political Economy.

[29]  John W. Tukey,et al.  Approximate behavior of the distribution of Winsorized t (Trimming/Winsorization 2) , 1968 .

[30]  S. Epstein Integration of the cognitive and the psychodynamic unconscious. , 1994, The American psychologist.

[31]  G. McClelland,et al.  Misleading Heuristics and Moderated Multiple Regression Models , 2001 .

[32]  R. Dhar,et al.  Consumer Choice between Hedonic and Utilitarian Goods , 2000 .

[33]  Jack L. Knetsch,et al.  Environmental policy implications of disparities between willingness to pay and compensation demanded measures of values , 1990 .

[34]  Colin Camerer,et al.  The Effects of Financial Incentives in Experiments: A Review and Capital-Labor-Production Framework , 1999 .

[35]  J. Knetsch,et al.  Willingness to Pay and Compensation Demanded: Experimental Evidence of an Unexpected Disparity in Measures of Value , 1984 .

[36]  R. Gregory,et al.  How precise are monetary representations of environmental improvements , 1995 .

[37]  A. Damasio Descartes' error: emotion, reason, and the human brain. avon books , 1994 .

[38]  Eric J. Johnson,et al.  Anchoring, Activation, and the Construction of Values. , 1999, Organizational behavior and human decision processes.

[39]  M. F. Luce,et al.  Choice Processing in Emotionally Difficult Decisions , 1997 .

[40]  P. Slovic The Construction of Preference , 1995 .

[41]  P. Slovic,et al.  Reversals of preference between bids and choices in gambling decisions. , 1971 .

[42]  Joel Huber,et al.  An Investigation of the Rationality of Consumer Valuations of Multiple Health Risks , 1987 .