The Factory-Free Economy: Outsourcing, Servitization and the Future of Industry

The shift towards a "factory-free" economy has drawn the attention of policy makers in North America and Europe. Some politicians have articulated alarming views, initiating mercantilist or ‘beggar-thy-neighbour' cost-competitiveness policies. Yet companies that concentrate research and design innovations at home but no longer have any factories there may be the norm in the future. This paper summarizes the key themes emerging from a conference on de-industrialization. De-industrialization is a process that happens over time in all countries, even China. The distinction between manufacturing and services is likely to become increasingly blurry. More manufacturing firms are engaging in services activities, and more wholesale firms are engaging in manufacturing. One optimistic perspective suggests that industrial country firms may be able to exploit the high-value added and skill-intensive activities associated with design and innovation, as well as distribution, which are all components of the global value chain for manufacturing. Although this ongoing transformation of the industrial economies may be consistent with evolving comparative advantage, it has significant short-run costs and requires far-sighted investments. These include the costs to workers who are caught in the shift from an industrial to a service economy, and the need to invest in new infrastructure and education to prepare coming generations for their changing roles.

[1]  E. Helpman,et al.  Export Versus FDI with Heterogeneous Firms , 2004 .

[2]  G. Duranton,et al.  Micro-Foundations of Urban Agglomeration Economies , 2003 .

[3]  Laurent Gobillon,et al.  In Economics and Social Sciences Working Papers Series the Productivity Advantages of Large Cities: Distinguishing Agglomeration from Firm Selection the Productivity Advantages of Large Cities: Distinguishing Agglomeration from Firm Selection , 2022 .

[4]  M. Crozet,et al.  The servitization of French manufacturing firms , 2014 .

[5]  E. Rossi-Hansberg,et al.  Organizations and Trade , 2008 .

[6]  T. Mayer,et al.  How Remote is the Offshoring Threat? , 2009 .

[7]  G. Santoni,et al.  Agglomeration economies and firm-level labor misallocation , 2019 .

[8]  A. Bernard,et al.  Factoryless Goods Producers in the US , 2013 .

[9]  S. Miroudot,et al.  Trade in Intermediate Goods and Services , 2009 .

[10]  William J. Baumol,et al.  American Economic Association Macroeconomics of Unbalanced Growth : The Anatomy of Urban Crisis , 2007 .

[11]  T. Mayer,et al.  The Effects at Home of Initiating Production Abroad: Evidence from Matched French Firms: What Happen , 2006 .

[12]  Gene M. Grossman,et al.  The Political Economy of Trade Policy: Papers in Honor of Jagdish Bhagwati , 1996 .

[13]  Gordon H. Hanson,et al.  The China Syndrome: Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the United States , 2012, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[14]  Zhi Wang,et al.  Tracing Value-Added and Double Counting in Gross Exports , 2012 .

[15]  Gordon H. Hanson,et al.  Importing Political Polarization? The Electoral Consequences of Rising Trade Exposure , 2016, American Economic Review.

[16]  P. Aghion,et al.  Industrial Policy and Competition , 2012 .

[17]  E. Helpman,et al.  Firms , Contracts , and Trade Structure ∗ Pol Antràs , 2003 .

[18]  David Hummels,et al.  The Nature and Growth of Vertical Specialization in World Trade , 1999 .

[19]  Teresa C. Fort Breaking Up Is Hard to Do: Why Firms Fragment Production Across Locations , 2013 .

[20]  Robert C. Johnson,et al.  Accounting for intermediates: Production sharing and trade in value added , 2012 .

[21]  Daron Acemoglu,et al.  Capital Deepening and Nonbalanced Economic Growth , 2006, Journal of Political Economy.

[22]  S. Yeaple Offshoring, Foreign Direct Investment, and the Structure of U.S. Trade , 2006 .

[23]  C. Pissarides,et al.  Structural Change in a Multi-Sector Model of Growth , 2004, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[24]  R. Baldwin,et al.  Global Supply Chains: Why They Emerged, Why They Matter, and Where They are Going , 2012 .

[25]  Margaret McMillan,et al.  Offshoring Jobs? Multinationals and U.S. Manufacturing Employment , 2011, Review of Economics and Statistics.

[26]  Nathan Nunn,et al.  Relationship Specificity, Incomplete Contracts and the Pattern of Trade , 2007 .

[27]  T. Mayer,et al.  Are Clusters More Resilient in Crises? Evidence from French Exporters in 2008-2009 , 2013 .

[28]  Paolo Epifani The Skill Bias of the US Trade Deficit , 2014 .

[29]  F. Toubal,et al.  Productivity, Relationship-Specific Inputs and the Sourcing Modes of Multinationals , 2011 .

[30]  M. Jansen,et al.  Globalization and Structural Change: Upheaval in the Nineties or in the Noughties? , 2017 .

[31]  A. Ebenstein,et al.  Why are American Workers Getting Poorer? China, Trade and Offshoring , 2015 .

[32]  Gordon H. Hanson,et al.  Foreign Investment, Outsourcing and Relative Wages , 1995 .

[33]  Thierry Verdier,et al.  A Theory of Defensive Skill-Based Innovation and Globalization , 2002 .

[34]  Jonathan Vogel,et al.  An Elementary Theory of Global Supply Chains , 2011, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[35]  Anders Åkerman,et al.  The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity: An Empirical Investigation , 2007 .

[36]  Timo Boppart Structural Change and the Kaldor Facts in a Growth Model with Relative Price Effects and Non-Gorman Preferences , 2011 .

[37]  Marc J. Melitz The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity , 2003 .

[38]  The Factory-Free Economy , 2016 .

[39]  A. Dixit,et al.  Trade and Protection with Multistage Production , 1981 .

[40]  Kalyan K. Sanyal,et al.  The Theory of Trade in Middle Products , 1982 .