Ideas and Growth

What is it about modern capitalist economies that allows them, in contrast to all earlier societies, to generate sustained growth in productivity and living standards? It is widely agreed that the productivity growth of the industrialized economies is mainly an ongoing intellectual achievement, a sustained flow of new ideas. Are these ideas the achievements of a few geniuses, Newton, Beethoven, and a handful of others, viewed as external to the activities of ordinary people? Are they the product of a specialized research sector, engaged in the invention of patent-protected processes over which they have monopoly rights? Both images are based on important features of reality and both have inspired interesting growth theories, but neither seems to me central. What is central, I believe, is that fact that the industrial revolution involved the emergence (or rapid expansion) of a class of educated people, thousands-now many millions-of people who spend entire careers exchanging ideas, solving work-related problems, generating new knowledge.

[1]  Milton H. Marquis,et al.  Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco , 2004 .

[2]  R. Nelson,et al.  Investment in humans, technological diffusion and economic growth , 1965 .

[3]  S. Rosen Learning by Experience as Joint Production , 1972 .

[4]  S. Rosen A Theory of Life Earnings , 1976, Journal of Political Economy.

[5]  James J. Heckman,et al.  A Life-Cycle Model of Earnings, Learning, and Consumption , 1976, Journal of Political Economy.

[6]  Boyan Jovanovic Job Matching and the Theory of Turnover , 1979, Journal of Political Economy.

[7]  P. Romer Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth , 1986, Journal of Political Economy.

[8]  Edward C. Prescott,et al.  Dynamic Coalitions: Engines of Growth , 1987 .

[9]  R. Lucas On the Mechanics of Economic Development , 1988 .

[10]  Boyan Jovanovic,et al.  The Growth and Diffusion of Knowledge , 1989 .

[11]  Nancy L. Stokey,et al.  Human Capital, Product Quality, and Growth , 1990 .

[12]  P. Romer Endogenous Technological Change , 1989, Journal of Political Economy.

[13]  G. Grossman,et al.  Innovation and growth in the global economy , 1993 .

[14]  R. Tamura,et al.  Income Convergence in an Endogeneous Growth Model , 1991, Journal of Political Economy.

[15]  Angus Deaton,et al.  Intertemporal Choice and Inequality , 1993, Journal of Political Economy.

[16]  Samuel Kortum,et al.  Research, Patenting, and Technological Change , 1997 .

[17]  K. Park A Theory of On-the-Job Learning , 1997 .

[18]  Charles I. Jones,et al.  Sources of U.S. Economic Growth in a World of Ideas , 1998 .

[19]  Lawrence F. Katz,et al.  Education and Income in the Early 20th Century: Evidence from the Prairies , 1999 .

[20]  Jonathan Eaton,et al.  International Technology Diffusion: Theory and Measurement , 1999 .

[21]  Lawrence F. Katz,et al.  Education and Income in the Early 20th Century: Evidence from the Prairies , 2000 .

[22]  Jess Benhabib,et al.  Human Capital and Technology Diffusion , 2002 .

[23]  Jonathan Eaton,et al.  Technology, Geography, and Trade , 2002 .

[24]  R. Lucas,et al.  Life Earnings and Rural-Urban Migration , 2004 .

[25]  Petra E. Todd,et al.  Earnings Functions, Rates of Return and Treatment Effects: The Mincer Equation and Beyond , 2005, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[26]  E. Hanushek,et al.  Handbook of the Economics of Education , 2006 .

[27]  Ellen R. McGrattan,et al.  Openness, Technology Capital, and Development , 2007 .

[28]  Esteban Rossi-Hansberg,et al.  Spin-Offs and the Market for Ideas , 2007 .

[29]  Spinoffs and the Market for Ideas , 2007 .

[30]  R. Lucas Trade and the Diffusion of the Industrial Revolution , 2007 .

[31]  Fernando Alvarez,et al.  Models of Idea Flows , 2008 .

[32]  Petra E. Todd,et al.  Last hired, first fired? black-white unemployment and the business cycle , 2007, Journal of Human Capital.

[33]  K. Arrow The Economic Implications of Learning by Doing , 1962 .