Unstable Values in Lifesaving Decisions

Although preferences and their underlying values are assumed to be stable by classical economic theory, empirical research has often shown deviations from normative principles and documented how preferences under risk are constructed and even shaped by seemingly irrelevant factors. What is remarkable about the construction of preference is its ubiquitous presence in nearly every decision-making domain. In accord with this idea, we argue that values (and valuations) can also be constructed and are therefore unstable. This is particularly evident in situations where valuations depend on affective responses (e.g., valuations of other people at risk). The research documenting mental imagery and attention as underlying processes of affective responses and research showing individual differences as moderators of these processes help explain why we do not hold stable values for saving human lives. Descriptive models show that our responses to people at risk are not always rational nor immune from biases common to other forms of preference. We suggest that the processes leading up to inconsistencies in valuations are strongly related to affect and affect regulation strategies. While most of us would probably agree that every life should be valued highly, our behaviors toward people in danger are often inconsistent with this belief.

[1]  Ilana Ritov,et al.  The ''Identified Victim'' Effect: An Identified Group, or Just a Single Individual? , 2005 .

[2]  P. Slovic,et al.  The affect heuristic , 2007, European Journal of Operational Research.

[3]  Stephen M. Johnson,et al.  Insensitivity to the Value of Human Life: A Study of Psychophysical Numbing , 1997 .

[4]  Elizabeth W. Dunn,et al.  Spending Money on Others Promotes Happiness , 2008, Science.

[5]  Mark Van Vugt,et al.  From Games to Giving: Social Value Orientation Predicts Donations to Noble Causes , 2007 .

[6]  S. Kosslyn,et al.  Mental imagery , 2013, Front. Psychol..

[7]  Deborah A. Small,et al.  Sympathy and callousness: The impact of deliberative thought on donations to identifiable and statistical victims. , 2007 .

[8]  Tehila Kogut,et al.  Someone to blame: When identifying a victim decreases helping , 2011 .

[9]  Christopher K. Hsee,et al.  Risk as Feelings , 2001, Psychological bulletin.

[10]  P. Slovic The Construction of Preference , 1995 .

[11]  M. S. Dixon,et al.  Values , 2000, Pediatrics.

[12]  D. Hamilton,et al.  Perceiving persons and groups. , 1996, Psychological review.

[13]  J. Andreoni IMPURE ALTRUISM AND DONATIONS TO PUBLIC GOODS: A THEORY OF WARM-GLOW GIVING* , 1990 .

[14]  Paul Slovic,et al.  The Irrational Economist: Making Decisions in a Dangerous World , 2010 .

[15]  Paul Slovic,et al.  Attentional mechanisms in the generation of sympathy , 2009, Judgment and Decision Making.

[16]  David J Ball,et al.  The Feeling of Risk: New Perspectives on Risk Perception , 2010 .

[17]  C. Daniel Batson,et al.  How social an animal? The human capacity for caring. , 1990 .

[18]  Paul Slovic,et al.  The affect heuristic , 2007, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[19]  Paul Slovic,et al.  “If I look at the mass I will never act”: Psychic numbing and genocide , 2007, Judgment and Decision Making.

[20]  P. Slovic,et al.  Affective Motivations to Help Others: A Two-Stage Model of Donation Decisions , 2011 .

[21]  Paul Slovic,et al.  The More Who Die, the Less We Care: Evidence from Natural Language Analysis of Online News Articles and Social Media Posts , 2020, Risk analysis : an official publication of the Society for Risk Analysis.

[22]  Paul Slovic,et al.  Psychic Numbing and Genocide , 2007 .