Information and Economic Interdependence

The pacifying effect of economic interdependence on conflict onset can be better understood in the context of "noisy" bargaining. Specifically, trading states bargain under less noisy conditions and, as a result, are unlikely to engage in militarized conflict. Noise is introduced into a generic take-it-or-leave-it bargaining game in the form of nonspecific asymmetric information about the defender's reservation value. Comparative statics show a positive monotonic relationship between variance in the noise term and the onset of militarized conflict. The relationships among economic interdependence, variance in the noise term, and conflict onset are evaluated with a Bayesian heteroskedastic probit model. Historical data are used to demonstrate that interdependence and uncertainty are related to each other and jointly related to the onset of militarized conflict. Uncertainty appears to be reduced by economic interdependence, and this leads to an enhanced probability of agreement short of a militarized clash.

[1]  B. Russett,et al.  Triangulating Peace: Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations , 2000 .

[2]  Janet M. Box-Steffensmeier,et al.  Duration models and proportional hazards in political science , 2001 .

[3]  Kenneth A. Schultz Do Democratic Institutions Constrain or Inform? Contrasting Two Institutional Perspectives on Democracy and War , 1999, International Organization.

[4]  Gary King,et al.  Binomial-Beta Hierarchical Models for Ecological Inference , 1999 .

[5]  Lucian Arye Bebchuk,et al.  Litigation and Settlement under Imperfect Information , 1984 .

[6]  S. Chib,et al.  Bayesian analysis of binary and polychotomous response data , 1993 .

[7]  Solomon W. Polachek,et al.  Liberalism and Interdependence: Extending the Trade-Conflict Model , 1999 .

[8]  William Reed,et al.  Regime types and status quo evaluations: Power transition theory and the democratic peace , 1996 .

[9]  Timothy Nordstrom,et al.  Risky Inference: Unobserved Treatment Effects in Conflict Studies , 2003 .

[10]  Andrew D. Martin,et al.  Multiparty electoral competition in the Netherlands and Germany: A model based on multinomial probit , 1998 .

[11]  Bruce Western,et al.  Causal Heterogeneity in Comparative Research: A Bayesian Hierarchical Modeling Approach , 1998 .

[12]  Bruce Russett,et al.  Clear and Clean: The Fixed Effects of the Liberal Peace , 2001, International Organization.

[13]  Simon Jackman,et al.  Estimation and Inference Are Missing Data Problems: Unifying Social Science Statistics via Bayesian Simulation , 2000, Political Analysis.

[14]  Michael D. Ward,et al.  Location, Location, Location: An MCMC Approach to Modeling the Spatial Context of War and Peace , 2002, Political Analysis.

[15]  J. O'neal,et al.  The Classical Liberals Were Right: Democracy, Interdependence, and Conflict, 1950–1985 , 1997 .

[16]  R. Michael Alvarez,et al.  American Ambivalence Towards Abortion Policy: Development of a Heteroskedastic Probit Model of Competing Values , 1995 .

[17]  Bruce Russett,et al.  Is the Liberal Peace Just an Artifact of Cold War , 1999 .

[18]  Bruce Russett,et al.  Assessing the Liberal Peace with Alternative Specifications: Trade Still Reduces Conflict , 1999 .

[19]  B. Russett,et al.  The Kantian Peace: The Pacific Benefits of Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations, 1885–1992 , 1999, World Politics.

[20]  Douglas M. Gibler An Extension of the Correlates of War Formal Alliance Dat Set, 1648-1815 , 1999 .

[21]  Alastair Smith,et al.  Testing theories of strategic choice: The example of crisis escalation , 1999 .

[22]  Gerald Schneider,et al.  Globalization and Peace: Assessing New Directions in the Study of Trade and Conflict , 1999 .

[23]  Daniel S. Geller Regions of War and Peace , 2004, Perspectives on Politics.

[24]  Zeev Maoz,et al.  Normative and Structural Causes of Democratic Peace, 1946–1986 , 1993, American Political Science Review.

[25]  Kevin M. Quinn,et al.  An integrated computational model of multiparty electoral competition , 2002 .

[26]  Nathaniel Beck,et al.  Taking Time Seriously: Time-Series-Cross-Section Analysis with a Binary Dependent Variable , 1998 .

[27]  James D. Morrow,et al.  Capabilities, Uncertainty, and Resolve: A Limited Information Model of Crisis Bargaining , 1989 .

[28]  J. F. Dulles,et al.  War or peace , 1950 .

[29]  Zvi Griliches,et al.  Specification Error in Probit Models , 1985 .

[30]  Andrew D. Martin,et al.  Voter Choice in Multi-Party Democracies: A Test of Competing Theories and Models , 1999 .

[31]  Karl W. Deutsch,et al.  Political Community And The North Atlantic Area , 1958 .

[32]  David P. Redlawsk,et al.  Advantages and Disadvantages of Cognitive Heuristics in Political Decision Making , 2001 .

[33]  Kevin A. Clarke Nonparametric Model Discrimination in International Relations , 2003 .

[34]  Erik Gartzke,et al.  Kant We All Just get Along? Opportunity, Willingness, and the Origins of the Democratic Peace , 1998 .

[35]  J. Fearon Rationalist explanations for war , 1995, International Organization.

[36]  Quan Li,et al.  Investing in the Peace: Economic Interdependence and International Conflict , 2001, International Organization.

[37]  Zeev Maoz,et al.  NORMATIVE AND STRUCTURAL CAUSES OF DEMOCRATIC PEACE , 1993 .

[38]  Jonathan N. Katz,et al.  Beyond Ordinary Logit: Taking Time Seriously in Binary Time-Series-Cross-Section Models , 1997 .

[39]  Simon Jackman,et al.  Bayesian Inference for Comparative Research , 1994, American Political Science Review.

[40]  J. David Singer,et al.  Militarized Interstate Disputes, 1816–1992: Rationale, Coding Rules, and Empirical Patterns , 1996 .

[41]  Simon Jackman,et al.  Estimation and Inference via Bayesian Simulation: An Introduction to Markov Chain Monte Carlo , 2000 .

[42]  Bradley P. Carlin,et al.  BAYES AND EMPIRICAL BAYES METHODS FOR DATA ANALYSIS , 1996, Stat. Comput..

[43]  S. Werner Deterring Intervention: The Stakes of War and Third-Party Involvement , 2000 .