An analytical and experimental comparison of maximal lottery schemes

Randomized voting rules are gaining increasing attention in social choice theory. A particularly interesting class of such rules are maximal lottery (ML) schemes, which were proposed by Peter Fishburn in 1984 and have been repeatedly recommended for practical use. However, the subtle differences between different ML schemes are often overlooked. Two canonical subsets of ML schemes are C1 -ML schemes (which only depend on unweighted majority comparisons) and C2 -ML schemes (which only depend on weighted majority comparisons). We prove that C2 -ML schemes are the only SD-efficient—but also among the most manipulable—ML schemes. While all ML schemes violate monotonicity, we show that they do satisfy a relative notion of monotonicity. We also evaluate the frequency of manipulable preference profiles and the degree of randomization of ML schemes via extensive computer simulations. In general, ML schemes are rarely manipulable and often do not randomize at all, especially when there are only few alternatives. The average degree of randomization of C2 -ML schemes is significantly lower than that of C1 -ML schemes.

[1]  Jennifer Ryan,et al.  Tournament games and positive tournaments , 1995, J. Graph Theory.

[2]  A. Gibbard Manipulation of Schemes That Mix Voting with Chance , 1977 .

[3]  Michel Regenwetter,et al.  The Unexpected Empirical Consensus Among Consensus Methods , 2007, Psychological science.

[4]  Jean-François Laslier,et al.  Aggregation of preferences with a variable set of alternatives , 2000, Soc. Choice Welf..

[5]  A. Sen,et al.  Collective Choice and Social Welfare , 2017 .

[6]  Felix Brandt,et al.  Universal pareto dominance and welfare for plausible utility functions , 2014, EC.

[7]  Felix Brandt,et al.  Proving the Incompatibility of Efficiency and Strategyproofness via SMT Solving , 2016, IJCAI.

[8]  Felix Brandt,et al.  On the tradeoff between efficiency and strategyproofness , 2018, Games Econ. Behav..

[9]  Felix Brandt,et al.  On the Discriminative Power of Tournament Solutions , 2014, OR.

[10]  P. Fishburn Condorcet Social Choice Functions , 1977 .

[11]  P. Fishburn Dominance in SSB utility theory , 1984 .

[12]  P. Fishburn Probabilistic Social Choice Based on Simple Voting Comparisons , 1984 .

[13]  Felix Brandt,et al.  Consistent Probabilistic Social Choice , 2015, ArXiv.

[14]  Dan S. Felsenthal,et al.  After two centuries, should condorcet's voting procedure be implemented? , 1992 .

[15]  Felix Brandt,et al.  On the structure of stable tournament solutions , 2016, Economic Theory.

[16]  P. Fishburn SSB Utility theory: an economic perspective , 1984 .

[17]  David Schmeidler,et al.  Strategic behaviour and a notion of ex ante efficiency in a voting model , 1986 .

[18]  F. Brandt,et al.  Arrovian Aggregation of Convex Preferences and Pairwise Utilitarianism , 2017, 1703.05519.

[19]  Hervé Moulin,et al.  A New Solution to the Random Assignment Problem , 2001, J. Econ. Theory.

[20]  Felix Brandt,et al.  A note on the McKelvey uncovered set and Pareto optimality , 2016, Soc. Choice Welf..

[21]  Felix Brandt,et al.  Arrovian Aggregation of Convex Preferences , 2017, Econometrica.

[22]  Felix Brandt,et al.  Welfare Maximization Entices Participation , 2015, Games Econ. Behav..

[23]  W. Gehrlein Condorcet's paradox and the likelihood of its occurrence: different perspectives on balanced preferences* , 2002 .

[24]  Felix Brandt,et al.  Strategic Abstention Based on Preference Extensions: Positive Results and Computer-Generated Impossibilities , 2015, IJCAI.

[25]  R. Rivest,et al.  An Optimal Single-Winner Preferential Voting System Based on Game Theory , 2010 .

[26]  Jean-François Laslier,et al.  Composition-consistent tournament solutions and social choice functions , 1996 .

[27]  Felix Brandt,et al.  On the Incompatibility of Efficiency and Strategyproofness in Randomized Social Choice , 2014, AAAI.

[28]  A. A. J. Marley,et al.  Behavioral Social Choice - Probabilistic Models, Statistical Inference, and Applications , 2006 .

[29]  Felix Brandt,et al.  Set-monotonicity implies Kelly-strategyproofness , 2010, Soc. Choice Welf..

[30]  J. Kelly,et al.  A strategy-proofness characterization of majority rule , 2003 .

[31]  Jean-François Laslier,et al.  A Theorem on Symmetric Two-Player Zero-Sum Games , 1997 .

[32]  Felix Brandt,et al.  On the tradeoff between economic efficiency and strategy proofness in randomized social choice , 2013, AAMAS.

[33]  Lê Nguyên Hoang,et al.  Strategy-proofness of the randomized Condorcet voting system , 2017, Soc. Choice Welf..

[34]  Nicholas Mattei,et al.  An Empirical Study of Voting Rules and Manipulation with Large Datasets , 2012 .

[35]  Jean-François Laslier,et al.  Tournament Solutions And Majority Voting , 1997 .

[36]  M. Breton,et al.  The Bipartisan Set of a Tournament Game , 1993 .

[37]  Bhaskar Dutta,et al.  Comparison functions and choice correspondences , 1999 .

[38]  Scott L. Feld,et al.  Who's Afraid of the Big Bad Cycle? Evidence from 36 Elections , 1992 .

[39]  William V. Gehrlein,et al.  Voting Paradoxes and Group Coherence , 2011 .

[40]  Felix Brandt,et al.  Strategyproof social choice when preferences and outcomes may contain ties , 2022, J. Econ. Theory.

[41]  Jean-François Laslier,et al.  In Silico Voting Experiments , 2010 .

[42]  H. Moulin Axioms of Cooperative Decision Making , 1988 .

[43]  Felix Brandt,et al.  Rolling the Dice : Recent Results in Probabilistic Social Choice , 2017 .

[44]  Florenz Plassmann,et al.  Modeling the Outcomes of Vote-Casting in Actual Elections , 2011 .

[45]  P. Fishburn The Theory Of Social Choice , 1973 .

[46]  B. Debord Caractérisation des matrices des préférences nettes et méthodes d'agrégation associées , 1987 .