Resisting Organizational Inertia: The Evolution of Industrial Districts

Industrial district success in Italy is often explained as a function oftraditional, homogenous communities, where close social ties and communityinstitutions supposedly create the trust necessary for collaborativeinter-firm relationships among small firms. However, such a functionalistapproach fails to explain why some districts prosper over time bydeveloping new process and product innovations, while others stagnatebecause they fail to respond to rapidly changing markets. We argue thatgreater attention to firm networks – both those internal and external to the district – and the role of key firms represents a more usefulanalytical method for understanding the evolution and formation ofindustrial districts.

[1]  A. Chandler,et al.  Regional Advantage: Culture and Competition in Silicon Valley and Route 128 , 1994 .

[2]  Carlo Trigilia The paradox of the region: economic regulation and the representation of interests , 1991 .

[3]  R. Putnam,et al.  Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. , 1994 .

[4]  Giacomo Becattini Scienza economica e trasformazioni sociali , 1979 .

[5]  G. Gereffi International trade and industrial upgrading in the apparel commodity chain , 1999 .

[6]  M. Lazerson,et al.  A New Phoenix?: Modern Putting-Out in the Modena Knitwear Industry , 1995 .

[7]  Sebastiano Brusco The Emilian model: productive decentralisation and social integration , 1982 .

[8]  W. Diebold,et al.  The Second Industrial Divide , 1985 .

[9]  S. Silverman Agricultural Organization, Social Structure, and Values in Italy: Amoral Familism Reconsidered1 , 1968 .

[10]  S. Winter,et al.  An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change.by Richard R. Nelson; Sidney G. Winter , 1987 .

[11]  B. Uzzi,et al.  Social Structure and Competition in Interfirm Networks: The Paradox of Embeddedness , 1997 .

[12]  Udo H. Staber 8. The Social Embeddedness of Industrial District Networks , 1996 .

[13]  J. Coleman Foundations of Social Theory , 1990 .

[14]  William Lazonick,et al.  Competitive Advantage on the Shop Floor , 1992 .

[15]  Charles Perrow,et al.  The New Competition: Institutions of Industrial Restructuring. , 1991 .

[16]  Carlo Poni World of Possibilities: Fashion as flexible production: the strategies of the Lyons silk merchants in the eighteenth century , 1997 .

[17]  Fernand Braudel,et al.  The wheels of commerce , 1982 .

[18]  G. D. Ottati The Economic Bases of Diffuse Industrialization , 1991 .

[19]  Howard E. Aldrich,et al.  Organizations and Environments , 1979 .

[20]  Mark S. Granovetter The Strength of Weak Ties , 1973, American Journal of Sociology.

[21]  Gabi Dei Ottati,et al.  Economic changes in the district of Prato in the 1980s: Towards a more conscious and organized industrial district , 1996 .

[22]  M. Lazerson,et al.  Organizational Growth of Small Firms - An Outcome of Markets and Hierarchies , 1988 .

[23]  Mark S. Granovetter Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness , 1985, American Journal of Sociology.

[24]  Elizabeth Garnsey,et al.  Proximity and complexity in the emergence of high technology industry: The oxbridge comparison , 1998 .

[25]  B. Harrison,et al.  Lean and Mean: The Changing Landscape of Corporate Power in the Age of Flexibility. , 1995 .

[26]  Gianni Lorenzoni,et al.  Constellations of Firms and New Ventures , 1988 .

[27]  Donald Harris,et al.  Benetton: Information Technology in Production and Distribution: A case study of the innovative potential of traditional sectors: F. Belussi, (SPRU occational papers no. 25) (SPRU, University of Sussex, Brighton, 1987) pp. 91, [UK pound]6.00 , 1988 .