Some Simple Tests of Rational Voting and Agenda Setting

This article analyzes election data that permit simple tests of rational voting and agenda setting. The voting test pertains to aggregate election results. The prediction is that when voters have single-peaked preferences, there will be more opposition to the second of two budget proposals that are voted on simultaneously. Unlike the standard binary choice setting, not all voters have weakly undominated voting strategies, but the game among the voters can be solved simply by iterative application of weak dominance. The agenda-setting prediction tested is that agenda setters should make one proposal rather than two when given the option. The data come from Oregon school district financial elections from 1980–83, years in which the rules for these elections were abruptly changed.

[1]  Kenneth K. Wong,et al.  Ten Thousand Democracies: Politics and Public Opinion in America's School Districts by Michael B. Berkman and Eric Plutzer , 2007 .

[2]  E. Plutzer,et al.  Ten Thousand Democracies: Politics and Public Opinion in America's School Districts , 2005 .

[3]  W. Mebane Coordination, Moderation, and Institutional Balancing in American Presidential and House Elections , 2000, American Political Science Review.

[4]  Wolfgang Pesendorfer,et al.  Abstention in Elections with Asymmetric Information and Diverse Preferences , 1999, American Political Science Review.

[5]  T. Feddersen,et al.  Voting Behavior and Information Aggregation in Elections with Private Information , 1997 .

[6]  G. Cox Strategic Voting Equilibria under the Single Nontransferable Vote , 1994, American Political Science Review.

[7]  Melvin J. Hinich,et al.  Advances in the spatial theory of voting , 1990 .

[8]  Thomas R. Palfrey,et al.  A mathematical proof of Duverger's Law , 1988 .

[9]  Vincent G. Munley,et al.  Economic Incentives and Political Institutions: Spending and Voting in School Budget Agenda , 1987 .

[10]  Thomas R. Palfrey,et al.  Voter Participation and Strategic Uncertainty , 1985, American Political Science Review.

[11]  W. Hartman,et al.  Effectiveness of Property Tax Relief in Oregon. , 1983 .

[12]  H. Rosenthal,et al.  MEDIAN VOTERS OR BUDGET MAXIMIZERS: EVIDENCE FROM SCHOOL EXPENDITURE REFERENDA , 1982 .

[13]  D. Rubinfeld,et al.  Micro Estimates of Public Spending Demand Functions and Tests of the Tiebout and Median-Voter Hypotheses , 1982, Journal of Political Economy.

[14]  H. Rosenthal,et al.  Asymmetric information and agenda control: The bases of monopoly power in public spending , 1982 .

[15]  Thomas Romer,et al.  Bureaucrats Versus Voters: On the Political Economy of Resource Allocation by Direct Democracy , 1979 .

[16]  Thomas Romer,et al.  Political resource allocation, controlled agendas, and the status quo , 1978 .

[17]  Joseph E. Stiglitz,et al.  The demand for education in public and private school systems , 1974 .

[18]  Peter C. Ordeshook,et al.  Abstentions and equilibrium in the electoral process , 1969 .

[19]  W. Riker,et al.  A Theory of the Calculus of Voting , 1968, American Political Science Review.

[20]  H. W. Dodds,et al.  Bureaucracy and Representative Government , 1937 .

[21]  Howard Rosenthal,et al.  THE SETTER MODEL , 1989 .

[22]  Peter C. Ordeshook,et al.  Models of strategic choice in politics , 1989 .

[23]  John O. Ledyard,et al.  The pure theory of large two-candidate elections , 1984 .