Predictable Behavior, Profits, and Attention

Stocks in the Shanghai market that hit upper price limits typically exhibit three characteristics: high returns, high volumes, and news coverage. We show that these price limit events attract investors' attention. Attention-grabbing events lead active individual investors to buy stocks they have not previously owned. Consistent with lowering investor search costs, events that affect a few (many) stocks lead to increased (decreased) buying. Upper price limit events coincide with initial price increases followed by statistically significant price mean reversion over the following week. Rational traders (statistical arbitrageurs) profit in response to attention-based buying. Smart traders accumulate shares on date t, sell shares on date t+1, and earn a daily average profit of 1.16%. We show the amount they invest predicts the degree of attention-based buying by individual investors. We end by decomposing individual investor trades in order to estimate losses attributable to behavioral biases. © 2007 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

[1]  Malcolm P. Baker,et al.  Limited Arbitrage in Mergers and Acquisitions , 2002 .

[2]  Brad M. Barber,et al.  Detecting Long-Run Abnormal Stock Returns: The Empirical Power and Specification of Test Statistics , 1997 .

[3]  C. Sims Implications of rational inattention , 2003 .

[4]  L. Summers,et al.  Noise Trader Risk in Financial Markets , 1990, Journal of Political Economy.

[5]  Lei Feng,et al.  Correlated Trading and Location , 2002 .

[6]  David Laibson,et al.  The Allocation of Attention: Theory and Evidence , 2003 .

[7]  Mark Grinblatt,et al.  What Makes Investors Trade? , 2000 .

[8]  Andrei Shleifer,et al.  Do Demand Curves for Stocks Slope Down , 1986 .

[9]  Jiang Wang,et al.  Trading Volume and Serial Correlation in Stock Returns , 1992 .

[10]  Ron Kaniel,et al.  The High Volume Return Premium , 2001 .

[11]  Shane A. Corwin,et al.  Limited Attention and the Allocation of Effort in Securities Trading , 2008 .

[12]  Massimo Massa,et al.  Behavioral Biases and Investment , 2005 .

[13]  A. Lynch Decision Frequency and Synchronization Across Agents: Implications for Aggregate Consumption and Equity Return , 1994 .

[14]  D. Hirshleifer,et al.  Limited Attention, Information Disclosure, and Financial Reporting , 2003 .

[15]  M. Parkinson The Extreme Value Method for Estimating the Variance of the Rate of Return , 1980 .

[16]  Brad M. Barber,et al.  Improved Methods for Tests of Long-Run Abnormal Stock Returns , 1999 .

[17]  L. Summers,et al.  Positive Feedback Investment Strategies and Destabilizing Rational Speculation , 1989 .

[18]  Lin Peng Learning with Information Capacity Constraints , 2005, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis.

[19]  Gur Huberman,et al.  Contagious Speculation and a Cure for Cancer: A Nonevent that Made Stock Prices Soar , 2001 .

[20]  John R. Graham,et al.  Do Dividend Clienteles Exist? Evidence on Dividend Preferences of Retail Investors , 2005 .

[21]  N. Mankiw,et al.  Sticky Information Versus Sticky Prices: A Proposal to Replace the New Keynesian Phillips Curve , 2001 .

[22]  Wei Xiongb,et al.  Investor attention , overconfidence and category learning , 2006 .

[23]  Kenneth A. Kim,et al.  Price Limit Performance: Evidence from the Tokyo Stock Exchange , 1997 .

[24]  M. Mitchell,et al.  Characteristics of Risk and Return in Risk Arbitrage , 2000 .

[25]  W. S. Chan,et al.  Stock Price Reaction to News and No-News: Drift and Reversal after Headlines , 2001 .

[26]  Brad M. Barber,et al.  All that Glitters: The Effect of Attention and News on the Buying Behavior of Individual and Institutional Investors , 2006 .