An Experiment on Nash Implementation

We perform an experimental test of a modification of the controversial canonical mechanism for Nash implementation, using 3 subjects in non-repeated groups, as well as 3 outcomes, states of nature, and integer choices. We find that this mechanism successfully implements the desired outcome a large majority of the time, providing empirical evidence for the feasibility of such implementation. In addition, the performance is further improved by imposing a fine on a dissident, so that the mechanism implements strict Nash equilibria. While our environment is stylized, our results offer hope that experiments can identify reasonable features for practical implementation mechanisms.

[1]  S. Siegel,et al.  Nonparametric Statistics for the Behavioral Sciences , 2022, The SAGE Encyclopedia of Research Design.

[2]  E. Maskin Nash Equilibrium and Welfare Optimality , 1999 .

[3]  A. Roth,et al.  Game-Theoretic Models and the Role of Information in Bargaining , 1979 .

[4]  Mark A Walker,et al.  A SIMPLE INCENTIVE COMPATIBLE SCHEME FOR ATTAINING , 1981 .

[5]  Rafael Repullo,et al.  A simple proof of Maskin's theorem on Nash implementation , 1987 .

[6]  J. Harsanyi Games with randomly disturbed payoffs: A new rationale for mixed-strategy equilibrium points , 1973 .

[7]  Martin Sefton,et al.  Abreu–Matsushima Mechanisms: Experimental Evidence , 1996 .

[8]  Richard D. McKelvey,et al.  Game forms for Nash implementation of general social choice correspondences , 1989 .

[9]  R. Mark Isaac,et al.  Group Size Effects in Public Goods Provision: The Voluntary Contributions Mechanism , 1988 .

[10]  M. Jackson Implementation in Undominated Strategies: A Look at Bounded Mechanisms , 1992 .

[11]  Mark A Walker,et al.  A Simple Incentive Compatible Scheme for Attaining Lindahl Allocations , 1981 .

[12]  F. Tang,et al.  Learning and incentive‐Compatible Mechanisms for Public Goods Provision: An Experimental Study , 1998, Journal of Political Economy.

[13]  R. Selten,et al.  Money Does Not Induce Risk Neutral Behavior, but Binary Lotteries Do even Worse , 1999 .

[14]  Robert W. Rosenthal,et al.  A NOTE ON ABREU-MATSUSHIMA MECHANISMS , 1992 .

[15]  George A. Akerlof,et al.  The Economic Consequences of Cognitive Dissonance , 1982 .

[16]  Motty Perry,et al.  Virtual Implementation in Backwards Induction , 1996 .

[17]  T. Groves,et al.  Optimal Allocation of Public Goods: A Solution to the 'Free Rider Problem' , 1977 .

[18]  Alex Kane,et al.  Measuring Risk Aversion from Excess Returns on a Stock Index , 1991 .

[19]  Miles S. Kimball,et al.  Preference Parameters and Behavioral Heterogeneity: An Experimental Approach in the Health and Retirement Survey , 1995 .

[20]  Douglas R. Glasnapp,et al.  Essentials of statistical analysis for the behavioral sciences , 1985 .

[21]  Hitoshi Matsushima,et al.  Virtual implementation in iteratively undominated strategies: complete information , 1992 .

[22]  Antonio Cabrales,et al.  Adaptive Dynamics and the Implementation Problem with Complete Information , 1999 .

[23]  John. Moore,et al.  Implementation in Environments with Complete Information (Now published as 'Implementation, Contracts and Renegotiation in Environments with Complete Information' in J-J Laffont (ed.), Advances in Economic Theory: Invited Papers to the World Congress of the Econometric Society, vol.I (1992), pp.182- , 1991 .

[24]  Philip J. Reny,et al.  A general solution to King Solomon's dilemma , 1999 .