State-Dependent Enforcement to Foster the Adoption of New Technologies
暂无分享,去创建一个
[1] A. Randall,et al. An Integrated Strategy to Reduce Monitoring and Enforcement Costs , 2000 .
[2] Abdoul G. Sam,et al. 1 Voluntary Pollution Reductions and the Enforcement of Environmental Law : An Empirical Study of the 33 / 50 Program , 2004 .
[3] Carmen Arguedas. Pollution standards, technology investment and fines for non-compliance , 2013, Journal of Regulatory Economics.
[4] S. Rousseau,et al. Learning About Compliance Under Asymmetric Information , 2008 .
[5] K. Telle,et al. Firms’ Compliance to Environmental Regulation: Is There Really a Paradox? , 2006 .
[6] J. Zofío,et al. Environmental Policy Instruments: Technology Adoption Incentives with Imperfect Compliance , 2010 .
[7] Sandra Rousseau,et al. Timing of environmental inspections: survival of the compliant , 2007 .
[8] D. Zilberman,et al. Regulating pollution with endogenous monitoring , 2002 .
[9] Jessica Coria,et al. Environmental policy, fuel prices and the switching to natural gas in Santiago, Chile☆ , 2009 .
[10] M. Raymond. Enforcement leverage when penalties are restricted: a reconsideration under asymmetric information , 1999 .
[11] Till Requate,et al. On the Incentives Created by Policy Instruments to Adopt Advanced Abatement Technology if Firms are Asymmetric , 2001 .
[12] L. Nadeau. EPA Effectiveness at Reducing the Duration of Plant-Level Noncompliance , 1997 .
[13] Paul Stoneman,et al. The Role of Supply Factors in the Diffusion of New Process Technology , 1983 .
[14] Enforcement Leverage with Fixed Inspection Capacity , 2013 .
[15] The role of warnings in regulation: keeping control with less punishment , 2004 .
[16] Christopher S. Decker,et al. Voluntary Environmental Investment and Responsive Regulation , 2006 .
[17] John Livernois,et al. Truth or consequences: Enforcing pollution standards with self-reporting , 1999 .
[18] J. Harford. Measurement error and state-dependent pollution control enforcement , 1991 .
[19] Thomas Sterner,et al. Refunded emission payments and diffusion of NOx abatement technologies in Sweden , 2015 .
[20] L. Friesen. Targeting Enforcement to Improve Compliance with Environmental Regulations , 2003 .
[21] Winston Harrington,et al. Enforcement leverage when penalties are restricted , 1988 .
[22] J. Coria,et al. On the interaction between imperfect compliance and technology adoption: taxes versus tradable emissions permits , 2010 .
[23] Wayne B. Gray,et al. The Effectiveness of Environmental Monitoring and Enforcement: A Review of the Empirical Evidence , 2011, Review of Environmental Economics and Policy.
[24] G. Brady,et al. Capital Turnover and Marketable Pollution Rights , 1988, The Journal of Law and Economics.
[25] John P. Weyant,et al. The role of technology for achieving climate policy objectives: overview of the EMF 27 study on global technology and climate policy strategies , 2014, Climatic Change.
[26] Robert N. Stavins,et al. For workshop on Architectures for Agreement: Addressing Global Climate Change in the Post Kyoto World , 2006 .
[27] David Pérez-Castrillo,et al. Optimal Enforcement Policy and Firms' Emissions and Compliance with Environmental Taxes , 2004, SSRN Electronic Journal.
[28] David Zilberman,et al. Policy for the adoption of new environmental monitoring technologies to manage stock externalities , 2012 .
[29] Grischa Perino,et al. Does more stringent environmental regulation induce or reduce technology adoption? When the rate of technology adoption is inverted u-shaped , 2012 .
[30] N. Rickman,et al. Regulatory dealing - revisiting the Harrington paradox , 1999 .
[31] J. Coria,et al. Regulatory Dealing: Technology Adoption Versus Enforcement Stringency of Emission Taxes , 2014 .
[32] W. Harrington,et al. A reconsideration of enforcement leverage when penalties are restricted , 1991 .
[33] A. Keeler,et al. Incomplete enforcement with endogenous regulatory choice , 1994 .
[34] Using competition to stimulate regulatory compliance: A tournament-based dynamic targeting mechanism , 2015 .