Do Risk and Time Experimental Choices Represent Individual Strategies for Coping with Poverty or Conformity to Social Norms?

This study revisits a debate played out in Current Anthropology as to whether subsistence decisions are the result of individual strategy to cope with poverty and increase wealth (advanced by Kuznar in 2001 and 2002) or conformity to social norms (advanced by Henrich and McElreath in 2002)—a debate that mirrors discussions within the behavioral sciences about individual versus social learning and within the social sciences about agency versus structure. This study, set in southwestern Madagascar, goes beyond previous investigations by examining the influence on choices in simple risk and time preference experiments of multiple measures of income, wealth, status, and need, as well as conformity at three nested levels: ethnicity (Masikoro, Mikea, and Vezo), village, and clan. Logistic regression models found that both wealth and income variables and social group memberships predict choices, where the best-fit model, evaluated with the Akaike Information Criterion, combined income and either ethnicity or village. The coinfluence of strategy and conformity on economic decisions suggests that humans habitually balance individual goals against social pressures. Equating wealth effects with individual learning and rational choice or equating ethnic effects with social learning and bounded rationality erects a series of false dichotomies.

[1]  J. Kufer,et al.  Behavioral Ecology and the Transition to Agriculture , 2006, Journal of Ethnobiology.

[2]  J. Dillon,et al.  Risk Attitudes of Subsistence Farmers in Northeast Brazil: A Sampling Approach , 1978 .

[3]  Samuel M. McClure,et al.  Time Discounting for Primary Rewards , 2007, The Journal of Neuroscience.

[4]  K. Laland Social learning strategies , 2004, Learning & behavior.

[5]  W. Bickel,et al.  Heroin addicts have higher discount rates for delayed rewards than non-drug-using controls. , 1999, Journal of experimental psychology. General.

[6]  M. Mauss The gift : Forms and functions of exchange in Archaic Societies / Marcel Mauss , 2020 .

[7]  Matthew Rabin,et al.  Diminishing Marginal Utility of Wealth Cannot Explain Risk Aversion , 2000 .

[8]  Werner-Reimers-Stiftung,et al.  Coping with uncertainty in food supply , 1991 .

[9]  Joseph Henrich,et al.  Decision-making, cultural transmission and adaptation in economic anthropology , 2001 .

[10]  M. Mauss Primitive Classification , 2022 .

[11]  L. J. Savage,et al.  The Utility Analysis of Choices Involving Risk , 1948, Journal of Political Economy.

[12]  A. Rogers Evolution and human choice over time. , 1997, Ciba Foundation symposium.

[13]  H. P. Binswanger,et al.  Risk aversion and credit constraints in farmers' decision‐making: A reinterpretation , 1983 .

[14]  C. L. Anderson,et al.  Discount Rates in Vietnam* , 2004, Economic Development and Cultural Change.

[15]  A. Tversky,et al.  Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk — Source link , 2007 .

[16]  W. Leonard,et al.  The origins of monetary income inequality: Patience, human capital, and division of labor , 2007 .

[17]  B. Hewlett,et al.  Co-Residence Patterns in Hunter-Gatherer Societies Show Unique Human Social Structure , 2011, Science.

[18]  R. Pérez‐Escamilla,et al.  An adapted version of the U.S. Department of Agriculture Food Insecurity module is a valid tool for assessing household food insecurity in Campinas, Brazil. , 2004, The Journal of nutrition.

[19]  Luke Rendell,et al.  ROGERS’ PARADOX RECAST AND RESOLVED: POPULATION STRUCTURE AND THE EVOLUTION OF SOCIAL LEARNING STRATEGIES , 2010, Evolution; international journal of organic evolution.

[20]  A. Tversky,et al.  Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases , 1974, Science.

[21]  R. MacCallum,et al.  Applications of structural equation modeling in psychological research. , 2000, Annual review of psychology.

[22]  H. Akaike A new look at the statistical model identification , 1974 .

[23]  J. Edwards,et al.  Methods for integrating moderation and mediation: a general analytical framework using moderated path analysis. , 2007, Psychological methods.

[24]  S. Vosti,et al.  Links between rural poverty and the environment in developing countries: Asset categories and investment poverty , 1995 .

[25]  S. Cook The Obsolete “Anti-Market” Mentality: A Critique of the Substantive Approach to Economic Anthropology , 1966 .

[26]  R. Mace The coevolution of human fertility and wealth inheritance strategies. , 1998, Philosophical transactions of the Royal Society of London. Series B, Biological sciences.

[27]  P. Samuelson A Note on Measurement of Utility , 1937 .

[28]  M. Fortes The Structure of Unilineal Descent Groups , 1953 .

[29]  J. Henrich,et al.  Why Humans Cooperate: A Cultural and Evolutionary Explanation , 2007 .

[30]  T. Caraco,et al.  An empirical demonstration of risk-sensitive foraging preferences , 1980, Animal Behaviour.

[31]  Colin Camerer,et al.  “Economic man” in cross-cultural perspective: Behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies , 2005, Behavioral and Brain Sciences.

[32]  D. Sperber,et al.  Defining and explaining culture (comments on Richerson and Boyd, Not by genes alone) , 2008 .

[33]  Timothy D. Wilson,et al.  Telling more than we can know: Verbal reports on mental processes. , 1977 .

[34]  A. Tversky,et al.  Choices, Values, and Frames , 2000 .

[35]  E. Smith Endless forms: human behavioural diversity and evolved universals , 2011, Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences.

[36]  Miles S. Kimball,et al.  Preference Parameters and Behavioral Heterogeneity: An Experimental Approach in the Health and Retirement Survey , 1995 .

[37]  N. Wilcox Stochastic models for binary discrete choice under risk: a critical primer and econometric comparison , 2008 .

[38]  P. Martinsson,et al.  Are Commercial Fishers Risk-Lovers? , 2004, Land Economics.

[39]  Kevin M. Murphy,et al.  A Theory of Rational Addiction , 1988, Journal of Political Economy.

[40]  R. Burling Maximization Theories and the Study of Economic Anthropology1 , 1962 .

[41]  R. Hertwig,et al.  Experimental practices in economics: A methodological challenge for psychologists? , 2001, Behavioral and Brain Sciences.

[42]  P. Richerson,et al.  Punishment allows the evolution of cooperation (or anything else) in sizable groups , 1992 .

[43]  R. L. Kelly,et al.  Mystification of the Mikea: Constructions of Foraging Identity in Southwest Madagascar , 2000, Journal of Anthropological Research.

[44]  Eric Alden Smith,et al.  Foundations of Human Sociality: Economic Experiments and Ethnographic Evidence from Fifteen Small‐Scale Societies , 2006 .

[45]  G. Evans,et al.  Childhood poverty, chronic stress, and adult working memory , 2009, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[46]  Stephen Jay Gould Bully for brontosaurus : further reflections in natural history , 1992 .

[47]  Juan C. Reboreda,et al.  Risk sensitivity in starlings: variability in food amount and food delay , 1991 .

[48]  B. Thomassen Anthropology and social theory , 2013 .

[49]  George M. Foster,et al.  Peasant Society and the Image of Limited Good , 1965 .

[50]  K. Kirby,et al.  Correlates of delay-discount rates: Evidence from Tsimane' Amerindians of the Bolivian rain forest , 2002 .

[51]  Steven J. Kachelmeier,et al.  Examining Risk Preferences under High Monetary Incentives: Experimental Evidence from the People's Republic of China , 1992 .

[52]  M. Gurven,et al.  Collective Action in Action: Prosocial Behavior in and out of the Laboratory , 2008 .

[53]  R. Boyd,et al.  Are Peasants Risk-Averse Decision Makers ? , 2022 .

[54]  Bram Tucker Applying Behavioral Ecology and Behavioral Economics to Conservation and Development Planning: An Example from the Mikea Forest, Madagascar , 2007, Human nature.

[55]  J. Tobias,et al.  Conservation issues and priorities in the Mikea Forest of south-west Madagascar , 2000, Oryx.

[56]  F. Cancian,et al.  Change and uncertainty in a Peasant Economy: The Maya Corn Farmers of Zinacantan. , 1973 .

[57]  B. Winterhalder,et al.  An evolutionary ecology perspective on diet choice, risk, and plant domestication , 1997 .

[58]  André Masson,et al.  Préférences face au risque et à l'avenir. Types d'épargnants , 2005 .

[59]  R. D'Andrade Human motives and cultural models: Schemas and motivation , 1992 .

[60]  Bram Tucker,et al.  GIVING, SCROUNGING, HIDING, AND SELLING: MINIMAL FOOD SHARING AMONG MIKEA OF MADAGASCAR , 2004 .

[61]  Jean Ensminger Theory in economic anthropology , 2002 .

[62]  Bram Tucker Perception of Interannual Covariation and Strategies for Risk Reduction among Mikea of Madagascar , 2007, Human nature.

[63]  W. Bickel,et al.  Behavioral and neuroeconomics of drug addiction: competing neural systems and temporal discounting processes. , 2007, Drug and alcohol dependence.

[64]  D. Holland,et al.  Cultural models in language and thought: An appraisal , 1987 .

[65]  S. Mullainathan,et al.  Do People Mean What They Say? Implications for Subjective Survey Data , 2001 .

[66]  Alex Mesoudi,et al.  Random copying, frequency-dependent copying and culture change , 2009 .

[67]  Travis J. Lybbert,et al.  Is Risk Aversion Really Correlated with Wealth? How Estimated Probabilities Introduce Spurious Correlation , 2007 .

[68]  Casey B. Mulligan,et al.  The Endogenous Determination of Time Preference , 1997 .

[69]  Bram Tucker,et al.  When the Wealthy Are Poor: Poverty Explanations and Local Perspectives in Southwestern Madagascar , 2011 .

[70]  W. Gould,et al.  An approximate likelihood-ratio test for ordinal response models , 1998 .

[71]  Lawrence A. Kuznar,et al.  Evolutionary applications of risk sensitivity models to socially stratified species: Comparison of sigmoid, concave, and linear functions , 2002 .

[72]  G. Chapman Temporal discounting and utility for health and money. , 1996, Journal of experimental psychology. Learning, memory, and cognition.

[73]  M. Chibnik Experimental economics in anthropology: A critical assessment , 2005 .

[74]  S. Pruett-Jones,et al.  Independent Versus Nonindependent Mate Choice: Do Females Copy Each Other? , 1992, The American Naturalist.

[75]  L. Schmidt Risk preferences and the timing of marriage and childbearing , 2008, Demography.

[76]  I. Fisher,et al.  The theory of interest , 1956 .

[77]  L. Kuznar,et al.  Deferred harvests: The transition from hunting to animal husbandry , 2001 .

[78]  Colin Camerer An experimental test of several generalized utility theories , 1989 .

[79]  F. Knight The economic nature of the firm: From Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit , 2009 .

[80]  F. Saussure,et al.  Course in General Linguistics , 1960 .

[81]  H. W. B.,et al.  The Principles of Sociology , 1897, Nature.

[82]  Timothy C. Bates,et al.  Explorer Personality accounts for stable preferences and expectations across a range of simple games , 2013 .

[83]  P. Wright Lemur traits and Madagascar ecology: coping with an island environment. , 1999, American journal of physical anthropology.

[84]  Bram Tucker,et al.  Constructing Mikea Identity: Past or Present Links to Forest and Foraging , 2001 .

[85]  P. Schoemaker,et al.  Probability Versus Certainty Equivalence Methods in Utility Measurement: Are they Equivalent? , 1985 .

[86]  JosephHenrich On Risk Preferences and Curvilinear Utility Curves , 2001 .

[87]  F. Marlowe Dictators and ultimatums in an egalitarian society of hunter-gatherers, the hadza of tanzania , 2004 .

[88]  H. Eggert,et al.  Small-scale Fishermen and Risk Preferences , 2007, Marine Resource Economics.

[89]  G. Becker,et al.  Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis with Special Reference to Education, Third Edition , 1993 .

[90]  S. Carey,et al.  Constraints on conceptual development: a case study of the acquisition of folkbiological and folksociological knowledge in Madagascar. , 2004, Monographs of the Society for Research in Child Development.

[91]  Timothy A. Kohler,et al.  The Calculus of Self Interest in the Development of Cooperation: Sociopolitical Development and Risk among the Northern Anasazi , 1992 .

[92]  R. Boyd,et al.  The evolution of conformist transmission and the emergence of between-group differences. , 1998 .

[93]  S. Stearns Trade-offs in life-history evolution , 1989 .

[94]  Emily C Lawrance Poverty and the Rate of Time Preference: Evidence from Panel Data , 1991, Journal of Political Economy.

[95]  T. Caraco,et al.  Risk-sensitivity: ambient temperature affects foraging choice , 1990, Animal Behaviour.

[96]  Bram Tucker,et al.  Foraging for Development: a Comparison of Food insecurity, Production, and risk among Farmers, Forest Foragers, and marine Foragers in Southwestern madagascar , 2010 .

[97]  Vicki G. Morwitz,et al.  Do Intentions Really Predict Behavior? Self-Generated Validity Effects in Survey Research , 2005 .

[98]  A. Mesoudi An experimental simulation of the “copy-successful-individuals” cultural learning strategy: adaptive landscapes, producer–scrounger dynamics, and informational access costs , 2008 .

[99]  Lawrence A. Kuznar,et al.  Rationality Wars and the War on Terror: Explaining Terrorism and Social Unrest , 2007 .

[100]  Kenneth J. Lenihan,et al.  Crime and Poverty - Some Experimental-Evidence from Ex-Offenders , 1980 .

[101]  G. A. Miller,et al.  Book Review Nisbett, R. , & Ross, L.Human inference: Strategies and shortcomings of social judgment.Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1980. , 1982 .

[102]  Joyce E. Berg,et al.  Risk preference instability across institutions: a dilemma. , 2005, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America.

[103]  Adam Smith,et al.  The Wealth of Nations , 1999 .

[104]  W. Bickel,et al.  Temporal discounting as a measure of executive function: insights from the competing neuro-behavioral decision system hypothesis of addiction. , 2008, Advances in health economics and health services research.

[105]  Sachiko Miyata Household's risk attitudes in Indonesian villages , 2003 .

[106]  B. Robberstad Estimation of private and social time preferences for health in northern Tanzania. , 2005, Social science & medicine.

[107]  Ferdinand de Saussure Course in General Linguistics , 1916 .

[108]  Walter Mischel,et al.  Predicting adolescent cognitive and self-regulatory competencies from preschool delay of gratification: Identifying diagnostic conditions. , 1990 .

[109]  H. Gintis,et al.  Costly signaling and cooperation. , 2001, Journal of theoretical biology.

[110]  B. Winterhalder,et al.  Risk-senstive adaptive tactics: Models and evidence from subsistence studies in biology and anthropology , 1999 .

[111]  E. Smith Making it real: Interpreting economic experiments , 2005, Behavioral and Brain Sciences.

[112]  R. Mcelreath,et al.  Shared Norms and the Evolution of Ethnic Markers , 2003, Current Anthropology.

[113]  M. Gurven,et al.  Culture Sometimes Matters: Intra-Cultural Variation in Pro-Social Behavior Among Tsimane Amerindians , 2005, Journal of economic behavior & organization.

[114]  Ruth Mace,et al.  Demography and ecology drive variation in cooperation across human populations , 2011, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[115]  L. Kuznar Risk Sensitivity and Value among Andean Pastoralists: Measures, Models, and Empirical Tests1 , 2001, Current Anthropology.

[116]  Martha J. Farah,et al.  Socioeconomic status and the brain: mechanistic insights from human and animal research , 2010, Nature Reviews Neuroscience.

[117]  A. Kroeber Classificatory Systems of Relationship. , 1909 .

[118]  Samuel M. McClure,et al.  Separate Neural Systems Value Immediate and Delayed Monetary Rewards , 2004, Science.

[119]  F. Cancian New Patterns of Stratification in the Zinacantan Cargo System , 1974, Journal of Anthropological Research.

[120]  Monique Borgerhoff Mulder,et al.  The Use of Quantitative Observational Techniques in Anthropology [and Comments and Replies] , 1985, Current Anthropology.

[121]  J. Cuzick,et al.  A Wilcoxon-type test for trend. , 1985, Statistics in medicine.

[122]  Mark Lubell,et al.  Conformists and mavericks: the empirics of frequency-dependent cultural transmission , 2008 .

[123]  Colin Camerer,et al.  Risk and time preferences: linking experimental and household survey data from Vietnam , 2010 .

[124]  S. J. Gould Bully for Brontosaurus. Further reflections on Natural History. London (Penguin) 1991. , 1991 .

[125]  R. Selten,et al.  Bounded rationality: The adaptive toolbox , 2000 .

[126]  G. Gigerenzer On Narrow Norms and Vague Heuristics: A Reply to Kahneman and Tversky (1996) , 1996 .

[127]  J. Höglund,et al.  Copying and sexual selection. , 1992, Trends in ecology & evolution.

[128]  William G. Frederick,et al.  Environmental constraints and sigmoid utility: implications for value, risk sensitivity, and social status , 2003 .

[129]  S. R. Jammalamadaka,et al.  Against the Gods: The Remarkable Story of Risk , 1999 .

[130]  Morten I. Lau,et al.  Estimating Individual Discount Rates in Denmark: A Field Experiment , 2002 .

[131]  T. Schelling Micromotives and Macrobehavior , 1978 .

[132]  C. Vega Rome Declaration on World Food Security , 2013 .

[133]  D. Hosmer,et al.  Goodness of fit tests for the multiple logistic regression model , 1980 .

[134]  A. Tversky,et al.  Prospect theory: analysis of decision under risk , 1979 .

[135]  Mansare Marikandia The Vezo of the Fiherena Coast, Southwest Madagascar: Yesterday and Today , 2001 .

[136]  Nan Lin,et al.  SOCIAL NETWORKS AND STATUS ATTAINMENT , 1999 .

[137]  S. Stich,et al.  Ending the Rationality Wars: How to Make Disputes About Human Rationality Disappear , 2002 .

[138]  P. Slovic The Construction of Preference , 1995 .

[139]  P. Richerson,et al.  Culture and the Evolutionary Process , 1988 .

[140]  S. Holden,et al.  On the measurement of risk aversion from experimental data , 2004 .

[141]  P. Todd,et al.  Simple Heuristics That Make Us Smart , 1999 .

[142]  Yaniv Hanoch,et al.  Domain Specificity in Experimental Measures and Participant Recruitment , 2006, Psychological science.

[143]  William T. Harbaugh,et al.  Risk Attitudes of Children and Adults: Choices Over Small and Large Probability Gains and Losses , 2002 .

[144]  Joaquim Silvestre,et al.  Does Risk Aversion or Attraction Depend on Income? An Experiment , 1999 .

[145]  Duncan James,et al.  Just Who Are You Calling Risk Averse? , 2000 .

[146]  Morten I. Lau,et al.  Estimating Risk Attitudes in Denmark: A Field Experiment , 2005 .

[147]  S. Bikhchandani,et al.  Learning from the behavior of others : conformity, fads, and informational cascades , 1998 .

[148]  J. Pender Discount rates and credit markets" Theory and evidence from rural india , 1996 .

[149]  S. Bikhchandani,et al.  You have printed the following article : A Theory of Fads , Fashion , Custom , and Cultural Change as Informational Cascades , 2007 .

[150]  [Reply]: On risk‐prone peasants: Cultural transmission or Sigmoid utility maximization? , 2002 .

[151]  M. Coller,et al.  Eliciting Individual Discount Rates , 1999 .

[152]  F. Bartlett Witchcraft, Oracles and Magic among the Azande , 1937, Nature.

[153]  R. Lind,et al.  Crime and Punishment Reconsidered , 1975, The Journal of Legal Studies.

[154]  EugeneS.Hunn Huna Tlingit Traditional Environmental Knowledge, Conservation, and the Management of a “Wilderness” Park1 , 2003 .

[155]  Veröffentlichungsversion,et al.  The Foundations of Cooperation in Economic Life , 2022 .

[156]  D Kahneman,et al.  On the reality of cognitive illusions. , 1996, Psychological review.

[157]  D. Bernoulli Exposition of a New Theory on the Measurement of Risk , 1954 .

[158]  L. Ross,et al.  Human Inference: Strategies and Shortcomings of Social Judgment. , 1981 .

[159]  F. Ellis Rural Livelihoods and Diversity in Developing Countries , 2000 .

[160]  Morten I. Lau,et al.  Eliciting Risk and Time Preferences , 2008 .

[161]  E. Ballestar An introduction to epigenetics. , 2011, Advances in experimental medicine and biology.

[162]  W. Leonard,et al.  Patience in a Foraging-Horticultural Society: A Test of Competing Hypotheses , 2004, Journal of Anthropological Research.

[163]  Margo Wilson,et al.  Competitiveness, risk taking, and violence: the young male syndrome , 1985, Ethology and Sociobiology.

[164]  P. Bourdieu Forms of Capital , 2002 .

[165]  P. Montague Neuroeconomics: a view from neuroscience. , 2007, Functional neurology.

[166]  R. Plutchik,et al.  Interrelationships among anxiety, aggression, impulsivity, and mood: A serotonergically linked cluster? , 1990, Psychiatry Research.

[167]  Balázs Szentes,et al.  Evolution of time preference by natural selection , 2009 .

[168]  W. Cavendish Empirical regularities in the poverty-environment relationship of rural households: evidence from Zimbabwe. , 2000 .

[169]  P. Wiessner,et al.  Experimental Games and Games of Life among the Ju/’hoan Bushmen , 2009, Current Anthropology.

[170]  Henry Saffer,et al.  Alcohol demand and risk preference. , 2008, Journal Of Economic Psychology.

[171]  Frank Cancian The Innovator's Situation: Upper-Middle-Class Conservatism in Agricultural Communities , 1979 .

[172]  Bram Tucker The behavioral ecology and economics of variation, risk, and diversification among Mikea forager-farmers of Madagascar , 2001 .

[173]  P. Richerson,et al.  • AN EVOLUTIONARY MODEL OF SOCIAL LEARNING: THE EFFECTS OF SPATIAL AND TEMPORAL VARIATON , 2013 .

[174]  James A. Tebbe Where Good Ideas Come From: The Natural History of Innovation , 2011 .

[175]  G. Dalton Economic Theory and Primitive Society1 , 1961 .

[176]  E. Wolf Closed Corporate Peasant Communities in Mesoamerica and Central Java , 1957, Southwestern Journal of Anthropology.

[177]  H. P. Binswanger Attitudes toward risk: Experimental measurement in rural india , 1980 .

[178]  Daniel Maxwell,et al.  Measuring food insecurity , 1996 .