Consumption, Durable Goods, and Transaction Costs

We study consumption of durable and nondurable goods when the durable good is subject to transaction costs. In the model, agents derive utility from a service flow of a durable good and a consumption flow of a nondurable good. The key feature of the model is the existence of a fixed transaction cost in the durable good market. The fixed cost induces an inaction region in the purchase of the durable good. More importantly, the inability to adjust the durable stock induces variation in consumption of the nondurable good over the inaction region. The variation is a function of the degree of complementarity between durable and nondurable goods in the period utility function, the rate of intertemporal substitution, and a precautionary motive induced by incomplete markets. We test the model using the PSID. Housing serves as the durable good. The data indicate an increase in consumption before moving to a smaller house and a decrease in consumption before moving to a larger house. This result is consistent with the model when there exists complementarity between the durable and nondurable good or when there is a strong precautionary effect.

[1]  J. Skinner Housing Wealth and Aggregate Saving , 1989 .

[2]  Dynamics of Aggregate Purchases of an Illiquid Durable Good with Risky Assets and Heterogeneous Agents , 2000 .

[3]  Gary V. Engelhardt House Prices and Home Owner Saving Behavior , 1995 .

[4]  Gary V. Engelhardt Consumption, Down Payments, and Liquidity Constraints , 1996 .

[5]  J. Skinner Housing and Saving in the United States , 1991 .

[6]  Adrian Pagan,et al.  Econometric Issues in the Analysis of Regressions with Generated Regressors. , 1984 .

[7]  Ricardo J. Caballero,et al.  Dynamic (S,S) Economies , 1991 .

[8]  J. L. Goodman,et al.  The accuracy of home owners' estimates of house value , 1992 .

[9]  Guy Laroque,et al.  Asset Pricing and Optimal Portfolio Choice in the Presence of Illiquid Durable Consumption Goods , 1987 .

[10]  James P. Smith,et al.  The Measurement and Structure of Household Wealth , 1999 .

[11]  Janice C. Eberly Adjustment of Consumers' Durables Stocks: Evidence from Automobile Purchases , 1994, Journal of Political Economy.

[12]  S. Rosen Manufactured Inequality , 1996, Journal of Labor Economics.

[13]  Marjorie Flavin,et al.  The Adjustment of Consumption to Changing Expectations About Future Income , 1981, Journal of Political Economy.

[14]  T. Yamashita,et al.  Owner-Occupied Housing and the Composition of the Household Portfolio Over the Life-Cycle , 1998 .

[15]  E. Prescott,et al.  Stochastic Monotonicity and Stationary Distributions for Dynamic Economies , 1992 .

[16]  Leonard J. Mirman,et al.  Optimal economic growth and uncertainty: The discounted case , 1972 .

[17]  Annette Vissing-Jorgensen,et al.  Towards an Explanation of Household Portfolio Choice Heterogeneity: Nonfinancial Income and Participation Cost Structures , 2002 .

[18]  W. Dunn Unemployment Risk, Precautionary Saving, and Durable Goods Purchase Decisions , 1998 .

[19]  J. Peek,et al.  Aggregate U.S. Private Saving: Conceptual Measures , 1989 .

[20]  Ricardo J. Caballero,et al.  Microeconomic Adjustment Hazards and Aggregate Dynamics , 1992 .

[21]  S. Zeldes Consumption and Liquidity Constraints: An Empirical Investigation , 1989, Journal of Political Economy.

[22]  Kul B. Bhatia Real Estate Assets and Consumer Spending , 1987 .

[23]  Consumption, Durable Goods, and Transaction Costs , 2003 .

[24]  L. Hansen Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments Estimators , 1982 .

[25]  Erik Hurst,et al.  Home is Where the Equity Is : Liquidity Constraints , Refinancing and Consumption , 2002 .

[26]  J. Beaulieu Optimal durable and nondurable consumption with transactions costs , 1993 .

[27]  E. Groves A Dissertation ON , 1928 .