Complete–market models of stochastic volatility

In the Black–Scholes option–pricing theory, asset prices are modelled as geometric Brownian motion with a fixed volatility parameter σ, and option prices are determined as functions of the underlying asset price. Options are in principle redundant in that their exercise values can be replicated by trading in the underlying. However, it is an empirical fact that the prices of exchange–traded options do not correspond to a fixed value of σ as the theory requires. This paper proposes a modelling framework in which certain options are non–redundant: these options and the underlying are modelled as autonomous financial assets, linked only by the boundary condition at exercise. A geometric condition is given, under which a complete market is obtained in this way, giving a consistent theory under which traded options as well as the underlying asset are used as hedging instruments.

[1]  David Nualart Rodón,et al.  The Malliavin Calculus and Related Topics , 2006 .

[2]  R. Tompkins Stock index futures markets: stochastic volatility models and smiles , 2001 .

[3]  N. Shephard,et al.  Non‐Gaussian Ornstein–Uhlenbeck‐based models and some of their uses in financial economics , 2001 .

[4]  Mark H. A. Davis Mathematics of Financial Markets , 2001 .

[5]  L. Rogers,et al.  Diffusions, Markov Processes and Martingales: References , 2000 .

[6]  G. Papanicolaou,et al.  Derivatives in Financial Markets with Stochastic Volatility , 2000 .

[7]  P. Schönbucher A market model for stochastic implied volatility , 1999, Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society of London. Series A: Mathematical, Physical and Engineering Sciences.

[8]  Kevin Dowd,et al.  Beyond Value at Risk: The New Science of Risk Management , 1998 .

[9]  S. Shreve,et al.  Robustness of the Black and Scholes Formula , 1998 .

[10]  L. Rogers,et al.  Complete Models with Stochastic Volatility , 1998 .

[11]  Emanuel Derman,et al.  STOCHASTIC IMPLIED TREES: ARBITRAGE PRICING WITH STOCHASTIC TERM AND STRIKE STRUCTURE OF VOLATILITY , 1998 .

[12]  N. Touzi,et al.  Contingent Claims and Market Completeness in a Stochastic Volatility Model , 1997 .

[13]  Bruce D. Grundy,et al.  General Properties of Option Prices , 1996 .

[14]  A. Harvey,et al.  5 Stochastic volatility , 1996 .

[15]  J. Rochet,et al.  DYNAMIC SPANNING: ARE OPTIONS AN APPROPRIATE INSTRUMENT? , 1996 .

[16]  D. Nualart The Malliavin Calculus and Related Topics , 1995 .

[17]  K. Elworthy,et al.  Formulae for the Derivatives of Heat Semigroups , 1994, 1911.10971.

[18]  Bruno Dupire Pricing with a Smile , 1994 .

[19]  S. Heston A Closed-Form Solution for Options with Stochastic Volatility with Applications to Bond and Currency Options , 1993 .

[20]  Robert J. Elliott,et al.  Integration by Parts, Homogeneous Chaos Expansions and Smooth Densities , 1989 .

[21]  J. Hull Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives , 1989 .

[22]  Alan G. White,et al.  The Pricing of Options on Assets with Stochastic Volatilities , 1987 .

[23]  J. Bismut Large Deviations and the Malliavin Calculus , 1984 .

[24]  Mark H. A. Davis Functionals of diffusion processes as stochastic integrals , 1980, Mathematical Proceedings of the Cambridge Philosophical Society.

[25]  L. Rogers,et al.  Diffusions, Markov processes, and martingales , 1979 .

[26]  F. Black,et al.  The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities , 1973, Journal of Political Economy.