A Comparison of Efficiency of Multicandidate Electoral Systems

A variety of electoral systems for single-winner, multicandidate elections are evaluated according to their tendency to (a) select the Condorcet candidate-the candidate who could beat each of the others in a two-way race-if one exists, and (b) select a candidate with high social (average) utility. The proportion of Condorcet candidates selected and a measure of social-utility efficiency under either random society or spatial model assumptions are estimated for seven electoral systems using Monte Carlo techniques. For the spatial model simulations, the candidates and voters are generated from multivariate normal distributions. Numbers of candidates and voters are varied, along with the number of spatial dimensions, the correlation structure, and the relative dispersion of candidates to voters. The Borda, Black, and Coombs methods perform well on both criteria, in sharp contrast to the performance of the plurality method. Approval voting, plurality with runoff, and the Hare system (preferential voting) provide mixed, but generally intermediate results. Finally, the results of the spatial model simulations suggest a multicandidate equilibrium for winningoriented candidates (under plurality, runoff, and Hare) that is not convergent to the median.

[1]  K. Arrow Social Choice and Individual Values , 1951 .

[2]  A. Downs An Economic Theory of Democracy , 1957 .

[3]  D. Black The theory of committees and elections , 1959 .

[4]  P. Converse,et al.  The American voter , 1960 .

[5]  M. Duverger Political Parties Their Organization and Activity in the Modern State , 1964 .

[6]  D. F. Morrison,et al.  Multivariate Statistical Methods , 1968 .

[7]  D. Hill,et al.  The Political Consequences of Electoral Laws , 1969 .

[8]  M. Hinich,et al.  An Expository Development of a Mathematical Model of the Electoral Process , 1970, American Political Science Review.

[9]  P. Fishburn A comparative analysis of group decision methods , 1971 .

[10]  A. Gibbard Manipulation of Voting Schemes: A General Result , 1973 .

[11]  N. Nie,et al.  Mass Belief Systems Revisited: Political Change and Attitude Structure , 1974, The Journal of Politics.

[12]  M. Satterthwaite Strategy-proofness and Arrow's conditions: Existence and correspondence theorems for voting procedures and social welfare functions , 1975 .

[13]  R. McKelvey Policy Related Voting and Electoral Equilibrium , 1975 .

[14]  Peter C. Fishburn,et al.  An analysis of simple two‐stage voting systems , 1976 .

[15]  John H. Aldrich,et al.  A Method of Scaling with Applications to the 1968 and 1972 Presidential Elections , 1977, American Political Science Review.

[16]  J. Harsanyi Rational behavior and bargaining equilibrium in games and social situations: Frontmatter , 1977 .

[17]  Peter C. Fishburn,et al.  An analysis of voting procedures with nonranked voting , 1977 .

[18]  Michael X Cohen,et al.  Toward Applicable Social Choice Theory: A Comparison of Social Choice Functions under Spatial Model Assumptions , 1978, American Political Science Review.

[19]  Philip D. Straffin,et al.  Topics in the theory of voting , 1980 .

[20]  Samuel Merrill,et al.  Strategic decisions under one-stage multi-candidate voting systems , 1981 .

[21]  Peter C. Fishburn,et al.  Approval voting, Condorcet's principle, and runoff elections , 1981 .

[22]  S. Merrill,et al.  Strategic Voting in Multicandidate Elections under Uncertainty and under Risk , 1981 .

[23]  W. Riker,et al.  The Two-party System and Duverger's Law: An Essay on the History of Political Science , 1982, American Political Science Review.

[24]  Robert F. Bordley,et al.  A Pragmatic Method for Evaluating Election Schemes through Simulation , 1983, American Political Science Review.

[25]  W. Gehrlein Condorcet's paradox , 1983 .