Conditional punishment is a double-edged sword in promoting cooperation

Punishment is widely recognized as an effective approach for averting from exploitation by free-riders in human society. However, punishment is costly, and thus rational individuals are unwilling to take the punishing action, resulting in the second-order free-rider problem. Recent experimental study evidences that individuals prefer conditional punishment, and their punishing decision depends on other members’ punishing decisions. In this work, we thus propose a theoretical model for conditional punishment and investigate how such conditional punishment influences cooperation in the public goods game. Considering conditional punishers only take the punishing action when the number of unconditional punishers exceeds a threshold number, we demonstrate that such conditional punishment induces the effect of a double-edged sword on the evolution of cooperation both in well-mixed and structured populations. Specifically, when it is relatively easy for conditional punishers to engage in the punishment activity corresponding to a low threshold value, cooperation can be promoted in comparison with the case without conditional punishment. Whereas when it is relatively difficult for conditional punishers to engage in the punishment activity corresponding to a high threshold value, cooperation is inhibited in comparison with the case without conditional punishment. Moreover, we verify that such double-edged sword effect exists in a wide range of model parameters and can be still observed in other different punishment regimes.

[1]  C. Hauert,et al.  Coevolutionary dynamics: from finite to infinite populations. , 2004, Physical review letters.

[2]  R. Boyd,et al.  Coordinated Punishment of Defectors Sustains Cooperation and Can Proliferate When Rare , 2010, Science.

[3]  T. Antal,et al.  Fixation of Strategies for an Evolutionary Game in Finite Populations , 2005, Bulletin of mathematical biology.

[4]  G. Szabó,et al.  Evolutionary prisoner's dilemma game on a square lattice , 1997, cond-mat/9710096.

[5]  C. Hauert,et al.  Punishing and abstaining for public goods , 2006, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[6]  F. C. Santos,et al.  Risk of collective failure provides an escape from the tragedy of the commons , 2011, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[7]  Tatsuya Sasaki,et al.  The evolution of cooperation by social exclusion , 2012, Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences.

[8]  Robert C. Wolpert,et al.  A Review of the , 1985 .

[9]  Conditional Punishment , 2014 .

[10]  M. Nowak,et al.  Evolution of cooperation by multilevel selection. , 2006, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America.

[11]  M. Nowak,et al.  Evolution of indirect reciprocity by image scoring , 1998, Nature.

[12]  David G. Rand,et al.  The evolution of antisocial punishment in optional public goods games. , 2011, Nature communications.

[13]  Attila Szolnoki,et al.  Benefits of Tolerance in Public Goods Games , 2015, Physical review. E, Statistical, nonlinear, and soft matter physics.

[14]  G. Brady Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action , 1993 .

[15]  Alex Thornton,et al.  Punishment and cooperation in nature. , 2012, Trends in ecology & evolution.

[16]  David G. Rand,et al.  Winners don’t punish , 2008, Nature.

[17]  Arne Traulsen,et al.  Emergence of responsible sanctions without second order free riders, antisocial punishment or spite , 2012, Scientific Reports.

[18]  Attila Szolnoki,et al.  Conditional Strategies and the Evolution of Cooperation in Spatial Public Goods Games , 2012, Physical review. E, Statistical, nonlinear, and soft matter physics.

[19]  P. Taylor,et al.  Evolutionarily Stable Strategies and Game Dynamics , 1978 .

[20]  Attila Szolnoki,et al.  Probabilistic sharing solves the problem of costly punishment , 2014, ArXiv.

[21]  I. Mysterud Unto others: The evolution and psychology of unselfish behavior , 1999 .

[22]  Bettina Rockenbach,et al.  The efficient interaction of indirect reciprocity and costly punishment , 2006, Nature.

[23]  Petter Holme,et al.  Prisoners' dilemma in real-world acquaintance networks: spikes and quasiequilibria induced by the interplay between structure and dynamics. , 2003, Physical review. E, Statistical, nonlinear, and soft matter physics.

[24]  R. Rob,et al.  Learning, Mutation, and Long Run Equilibria in Games , 1993 .

[25]  Andrew M. Colman,et al.  The puzzle of cooperation , 2006, Nature.

[26]  György Szabó,et al.  Phase transitions and volunteering in spatial public goods games. , 2002, Physical review letters.

[27]  Attila Szolnoki,et al.  Individual wealth-based selection supports cooperation in spatial public goods games , 2016, Scientific Reports.

[28]  Alessandro Tavoni,et al.  Inequality, communication, and the avoidance of disastrous climate change in a public goods game , 2011, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[29]  Attila Szolnoki,et al.  Statistical Physics of Human Cooperation , 2017, ArXiv.

[30]  R. Boyd,et al.  Indirect reciprocity can stabilize cooperation without the second-order free rider problem , 2004, Nature.

[31]  E. Fehr,et al.  Cooperation and Punishment in Public Goods Experiments , 1999, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[32]  C. Hauert,et al.  Volunteering as Red Queen Mechanism for Cooperation in Public Goods Games , 2002, Science.

[33]  F. C. Santos,et al.  Evolutionary dynamics of collective action in N-person stag hunt dilemmas , 2009, Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences.

[34]  Long Wang,et al.  Social exclusion in finite populations. , 2015, Physical review. E, Statistical, nonlinear, and soft matter physics.

[35]  L. Putterman,et al.  Who to punish? Individual decisions and majority rule in mitigating the free rider problem , 2009 .

[36]  Martin A. Nowak,et al.  The evolution of anti-social punishment in optional public goods games , 2019 .

[37]  Attila Szolnoki,et al.  Effectiveness of conditional punishment for the evolution of public cooperation. , 2013, Journal of theoretical biology.

[38]  P. Wiessner Norm enforcement among the Ju/’hoansi Bushmen , 2005, Human nature.

[39]  Arne Traulsen,et al.  Pairwise comparison and selection temperature in evolutionary game dynamics. , 2007, Journal of theoretical biology.

[40]  Oliver P Hauser,et al.  Punishment does not promote cooperation under exploration dynamics when anti-social punishment is possible. , 2014, Journal of theoretical biology.

[41]  Xiaojie Chen,et al.  First carrot, then stick: how the adaptive hybridization of incentives promotes cooperation , 2015, Journal of The Royal Society Interface.

[42]  M. Milinski,et al.  Volunteering leads to rock–paper–scissors dynamics in a public goods game , 2003, Nature.

[43]  Attila Szolnoki,et al.  Evolutionary dynamics of group interactions on structured populations: a review , 2013, Journal of The Royal Society Interface.

[44]  Baokui Wang,et al.  Effects of income redistribution on the evolution of cooperation in spatial public goods games , 2016 .

[45]  M. Perc,et al.  Self-organization of punishment in structured populations , 2012, 1203.6900.

[46]  Martin A. Nowak,et al.  Public Goods With Punishment and Abstaining in Finite and Infinite Populations , 2008, Biological theory.

[47]  Arne Traulsen,et al.  Heterogeneity in background fitness acts as a suppressor of selection. , 2014, Journal of theoretical biology.

[48]  J. Henrich,et al.  Costly Punishment Across Human Societies , 2006, Science.

[49]  C. Hauert,et al.  Via Freedom to Coercion: The Emergence of Costly Punishment , 2007, Science.

[50]  Matjaž Perc,et al.  Phase transitions in models of human cooperation , 2016 .

[51]  S. Schneider What is 'dangerous' climate change? , 2001, Nature.

[52]  C. Hauert,et al.  Replicator dynamics for optional public good games. , 2002, Journal of theoretical biology.

[53]  Josef Hofbauer,et al.  Evolutionary Games and Population Dynamics , 1998 .

[54]  Manfred Milinski,et al.  The Calculus of Selfishness , 2011 .

[55]  Long Wang,et al.  Interactive diversity promotes the evolution of cooperation in structured populations , 2016 .

[56]  Amy R. Poteete,et al.  Working Together: Collective Action, the Commons, and Multiple Methods in Practice , 2010 .

[57]  S. Gächter,et al.  The Long-Run Benefits of Punishment , 2008, Science.

[58]  P J Richerson,et al.  Group selection among alternative evolutionarily stable strategies. , 1990, Journal of theoretical biology.

[59]  C. Hauert,et al.  Reputation-based partner choice promotes cooperation in social networks. , 2008, Physical review. E, Statistical, nonlinear, and soft matter physics.

[60]  G. Szabó,et al.  Evolutionary games on graphs , 2006, cond-mat/0607344.

[61]  Arne Traulsen,et al.  Social learning promotes institutions for governing the commons , 2010, Nature.

[62]  Long Wang,et al.  Multiple tolerances dilute the second order cooperative dilemma , 2017 .

[63]  Martin A. Nowak,et al.  Evolutionary dynamics on any population structure , 2016, Nature.

[64]  Drew Fudenberg,et al.  Imitation Processes with Small Mutations , 2004, J. Econ. Theory.

[65]  M. Nowak,et al.  The effect of spatial fitness heterogeneity on fixation probability , 2017, 1709.03031.

[66]  F. C. Santos,et al.  Emergence of fairness in repeated group interactions. , 2012, Physical review letters.

[67]  Attila Szolnoki,et al.  Competition of tolerant strategies in the spatial public goods game , 2016, 1607.08600.

[68]  James H. Fowler,et al.  Human cooperation: Second-order free-riding problem solved? , 2005, Nature.