Measuring and modeling varia-tion in the risk-return tradeoff

Are excess stock market returns predictable over time and, if so, at what horizons and with which economic indicators? Can stock return predictability be explained by changes in stock market volatility? How does the mean return per unit risk change over time? This chapter reviews what is known about the time-series evolution of the risk-return tradeoff for stock market investment, and presents some new empirical evidence using a proxy for the log consumption-aggregate wealth ratio as a predictor of both the mean and volatility of excess stock market returns. We characterize the risk-return tradeoff as the conditional expected excess return on a broad stock market index divided by its conditional standard deviation, a quantity commonly known as the Sharpe ratio. Our own investigation suggests that variation in the equity riskpremium is strongly negatively linked to variation in market volatility, at odds with leading asset pricing models. Since the conditional volatility and conditional mean move in opposite directions, the degree of countercyclicality in the Sharpe ratio that we document here is far more dramatic than that produced by existing equilibrium models of financial market behavior, which completely miss the sheer magnitude of variation in the price of stock market risk; leading asset pricing paradigms leave a “Sharpe ratio volatility puzzleÔ that remains to be explained.

[1]  Consumption, Aggregate Wealth and Expected Stock Returns , 1999 .

[2]  L. Glosten,et al.  Economic Significance of Predictable Variations in Stock Index Returns , 1989 .

[3]  Allan W. Gregory,et al.  Theoretical Relations Between Risk Premiums and Conditional Variances , 1993 .

[4]  A. Blinder,et al.  The Time Series Consumption Function Revisited , 1985 .

[5]  Michael W. McCracken Asymptotics for Out of Sample Tests of Causality , 1998 .

[6]  W. Sharpe,et al.  Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium under Conditions of Risk , 2007 .

[7]  Barbara Rossi,et al.  OPTIMAL TESTS FOR NESTED MODEL SELECTION WITH UNDERLYING PARAMETER INSTABILITY , 2005, Econometric Theory.

[8]  R. Hodrick Dividend Yields and Expected Stock Returns: Alternative Procedures for Interference and Measurement , 1991 .

[9]  Simon M. Potter,et al.  Understanding Trend and Cycle in Asset Values: Reevaluating the Wealth Effect on Consumption , 2004 .

[10]  J. Lintner SECURITY PRICES, RISK, AND MAXIMAL GAINS FROM DIVERSIFICATION , 1965 .

[11]  Campbell R. Harvey The World Price of Covariance Risk , 1991 .

[12]  J. Poterba,et al.  Stock Ownership Patterns, Stock Market Fluctuations, and Consumption , 1995 .

[13]  W. Sharpe CAPITAL ASSET PRICES: A THEORY OF MARKET EQUILIBRIUM UNDER CONDITIONS OF RISK* , 1964 .

[14]  J. Wooldridge,et al.  A Capital Asset Pricing Model with Time-Varying Covariances , 1988, Journal of Political Economy.

[15]  K. French,et al.  Expected stock returns and volatility , 1987 .

[16]  J. Cochrane Permanent and Transitory Components of GNP and Stock Prices , 1994 .

[17]  Darrell Duffie,et al.  Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers , 1996, Journal of Political Economy.

[18]  Campbell R. Harvey Time-Varying Conditional Covariances in Tests of Asset Pricing Models , 1989 .

[19]  J. Lewellen,et al.  Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios , 2002 .

[20]  J. Cochrane Explaining the Variance of Price Dividend Ratios , 1989 .

[21]  T. Bollerslev,et al.  Generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity , 1986 .

[22]  Sergei Sarkissian,et al.  Spurious Regressions in Financial Economics? , 2002 .

[23]  Yuming Li,et al.  Expected Returns and Habit Persistence , 2000 .

[24]  G. Schwert Why Does Stock Market Volatility Change Over Time? , 1988 .

[25]  S. Price,et al.  The Dynamics of Consumers' Expenditure: The UK Consumption Ecm Redux , 2003 .

[26]  J. Cochrane,et al.  Volatility Tests and Efficient Markets: A Review Essay , 1991 .

[27]  J. Campbell Stock Returns and the Term Structure , 1985 .

[28]  Michael W. Brandt,et al.  On the Relationship between the Conditional Mean and Volatility of Stock Returns: A Latent VAR Approach , 2002 .

[29]  Todd E. Clark,et al.  Forecast-Based Model Selection in the Presence of Structural Breaks , 2002 .

[30]  E. Fama,et al.  BUSINESS CONDITIONS AND EXPECTED RETURNS ON STOCKS AND BONDS , 1989 .

[31]  M. Ogaki,et al.  A cointegration approach to estimating preference parameters , 1997 .

[32]  Hui Guo,et al.  On the Out-of-Sample Predictability of Stock Market Returns * , 2006 .

[33]  R. Shiller,et al.  The Dividend-Price Ratio and Expectations of Future Dividends and Discount Factors , 1986 .

[34]  R. Mehra,et al.  THE EQUITY PREMIUM A Puzzle , 1985 .

[35]  Mark W. Watson,et al.  A SIMPLE ESTIMATOR OF COINTEGRATING VECTORS IN HIGHER ORDER INTEGRATED SYSTEMS , 1993 .

[36]  Campbell R. Harvey The Specification of Conditional Expectations , 1991 .

[37]  E. Ghysels,et al.  There is a Risk-Return Tradeoff after All , 2004 .

[38]  Andrew B. Abel,et al.  Stock Prices Under Time-Varying Dividend Risk: an Exact Solution in an Infinite-Horizon General Equilibrium Model , 1988 .

[39]  M. Lettau,et al.  Expected Returns and Expected Dividend Growth , 2002 .

[40]  Sydney C. Ludvigson,et al.  Consumption, Aggregate Wealth and Expected Stock Returns , 1999 .

[41]  Todd E. Clark,et al.  Tests of Equal Forecast Accuracy and Encompassing for Nested Models , 1999 .

[42]  Prospect Theory and Asset Prices , 1999 .

[43]  Jacob Boudoukh,et al.  Nonlinearities in the Relation Between the Equity Risk Premium and the Term Structure , 1997 .

[44]  J. Lewellen,et al.  The time-series relations among expected return, risk, and book-to-market ☆ , 1999 .

[45]  R. Stambaugh,et al.  Predictive Regressions , 1999 .

[46]  C. Nelson,et al.  Predictable Stock Returns: The Role of Small Sample Bias , 1993 .

[47]  F. Diebold,et al.  How Relevant is Volatility Forecasting for Financial Risk Management? , 1997, Review of Economics and Statistics.

[48]  T. Andersen THE ECONOMETRICS OF FINANCIAL MARKETS , 1998, Econometric Theory.

[49]  Owen A. Lamont Earnings and Expected Returns , 1996 .

[50]  Daniel B. Nelson CONDITIONAL HETEROSKEDASTICITY IN ASSET RETURNS: A NEW APPROACH , 1991 .

[51]  Rossen Valkanov Long-horizon regressions: theoretical results and applications , 2003 .

[52]  J. Campbell,et al.  By Force of Habit: A Consumption‐Based Explanation of Aggregate Stock Market Behavior , 1995, Journal of Political Economy.

[53]  L. Kilian,et al.  In-Sample or Out-of-Sample Tests of Predictability: Which One Should We Use? , 2002, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[54]  G. Duffee Do forecasts of stock returns also forecast covariances ? , 2002 .

[55]  David E. Rapach,et al.  In-sample vs. out-of-sample tests of stock return predictability in the context of data mining , 2006 .

[56]  E. Fama,et al.  Dividend yields and expected stock returns , 1988 .

[57]  Andrew J. Patton,et al.  What good is a volatility model? , 2001 .

[58]  Robert F. Whitelaw Time Variations and Covariations in the Expectation and Volatility of Stock Market Returns , 1994 .

[59]  Robert F. Whitelaw Stock Market Risk and Return: An Equilibrium Approach , 1997 .

[60]  Campbell R. Harvey,et al.  The Variation of Economic Risk Premiums , 1990, Journal of Political Economy.

[61]  John Y. Campbell,et al.  Understanding Risk and Return , 1993, Journal of Political Economy.

[62]  L. Glosten,et al.  On the Relation between the Expected Value and the Volatility of the Nominal Excess Return on Stocks , 1993 .

[63]  J. Cochrane,et al.  Where is the market going ? Uncertain facts and novel theories , 1997 .

[64]  R. Engle New Frontiers for Arch Models , 2002 .

[65]  G. Schwert Why Does Stock Market Volatility Change Over Time , 1988 .