Structural Modeling and Policy Simulation

A primary goal of research in marketing is to evaluate and recommend optimal policies for marketing actions, or “instruments” in the terminology of Franses (2005). In this respect, marketing is a very policy-oriented field, and it is ironic that so much published research skirts the issue of policy evaluation. Franses’s article draws much needed attention to the question of what sort of model is usable for policy simulation and evaluation. Our perspective on what constitutes a valid model for policy evaluation differs from Franses’s view, but we believe our view complements his in many important respects. We also strongly believe that marketing has much to contribute to the literature on structural modeling. We outline some of what we believe are the advantages for marketing scholars of using structural modeling for policy evaluations and some of the challenges presented by marketing problems. Franses focuses on a reduced-form sales response model in which the outcome variable (yt) is modeled conditional on marketing variables (xt). If customers anticipate future marketing actions and take these into account in responding to the environment at time t, an additional equation is appended to the system to describe the evolution of the xt variables. In Franses’s view, this system can be used for policy simulation if both the y and x equations have timeinvariant parameters. That is, the Lucas critique, which implies that parameters of reduced-form models change if the policy regime changes, does not apply. According to Franses, a model must pass standard diagnostics, possess good predictive properties, and exhibit parameter stability to be useful for policy simulation. We applaud the attention Franses is bringing to model diagnostics. We believe that structural work in both marketing and economics should pay close attention to the central features of the data. Increased use of model diagnostics will help ensure that structural models are capable of capturing these features. However, we do not believe that all the criteria proposed by Franses, such as out-of-sample validity and parameter stability, are either necessary or sufficient to render a model useful for policy simulation. Reduced-form models can pass all diagnostics, including out-of-sample validation, and still provide misleading predictions about the effects of policy changes. Reduced-form

[1]  S. Villas-Boas Vertical Contracts between Manufacturers and Retailers: Inference with Limited Data , 2004 .

[2]  Steven T. Berry Estimating Discrete-Choice Models of Product Differentiation , 1994 .

[3]  Peter E. Rossi,et al.  Modeling Consumer Demand for Variety , 2002 .

[4]  M. Keane,et al.  Decision-Making Under Uncertainty: Capturing Dynamic Brand Choice Processes in Turbulent Consumer Goods Markets , 1996 .

[5]  K. Sudhir,et al.  Structural Analysis of Manufacturer Pricing in the Presence of a Strategic Retailer , 2001 .

[6]  Harald J. van Heerde,et al.  Marketing Models and the Lucas Critique , 2004 .

[7]  Richard Schmalensee,et al.  MEASURING MARKET POWER IN THE READY-TO-EAT CEREAL INDUSTRY BY AVIV NEVO , 2001 .

[8]  J. M. Villas-Boas,et al.  Endogeneity in Brand Choice Models , 1999 .

[9]  J. M. Villas-Boas,et al.  Retailer, Manufacturers, and Individual Consumers: Modeling the Supply Side in the Ketchup Marketplace , 2005 .

[10]  Kannan Srinivasan,et al.  Role of Forgetting in Memory-Based Choice Decisions: A Structural Model , 2004 .

[11]  Peter E. Rossi,et al.  Response Modeling with Non-Random Marketing Mix Variables , 2003 .

[12]  Pradeep K. Chintagunta,et al.  Estimating a Stockkeeping-Unit-Level Brand Choice Model that Combines Household Panel Data and Store Data , 2005 .

[13]  Pradeep K. Chintagunta,et al.  Balancing Profitability and Customer Welfare in a Supermarket Chain , 2003 .

[14]  Puneet Manchanda,et al.  An Empirical Model of Advertising Dynamics , 2004 .

[15]  I. Hendel,et al.  Estimating Multiple-Discrete Choice Models: An Application to Computeri-Zzation Returns , 1994 .

[16]  M. Keane,et al.  Brand and Quantity Choice Dynamics Under Price Uncertainty , 2003 .

[17]  Diagnostics, Expectations, and Endogeneity , 2005 .

[18]  David Besanko,et al.  Logit Demand Estimation Under Competitive Pricing Behavior: An Equilibrium Framework , 1998 .

[19]  Dick R. Wittink,et al.  Econometric Models for Marketing Decisions , 2005 .

[20]  Eric T. Bradlow,et al.  Why Analyst Overconfidence About the Functional Form of Demand Models Can Lead to Overpricing , 1999 .

[21]  Steven T. Berry,et al.  Automobile Prices in Market Equilibrium , 1995 .

[22]  Philip Hans Franses,et al.  On the Use of Econometric Models for Policy Simulation in Marketing , 2005 .

[23]  K. Srinivasan,et al.  Price Uncertainty and Consumer Search: A Structural Model of Consideration Set Formation , 2003 .

[24]  Puneet Manchanda,et al.  An Empirical Model of Advertising Dynamics , 2004 .

[25]  Peter E. Rossi,et al.  Response Modeling with Nonrandom Marketing-Mix Variables , 2004 .

[26]  Jean-Pierre Dubé Multiple Discreteness and Product Differentiation: Demand for Carbonated Soft Drinks , 2004 .

[27]  Vijay Mahajan,et al.  Unobserved Retailer Behavior in Multimarket Data: Joint Spatial Dependence in Market Shares and Promotion Variables , 2001 .

[28]  Aviv Nevo Measuring Market Power in the Ready-to-Eat Cereal Industry , 1998 .