Fat: The Displacement of Nonproduction Workers from U.S. Manufacturing Industries

IN THE LONG RUN American industry has relied increasingly on nonproduction staff, yet in the last decade many white-collar employees have been squeezed out of large corporations in the name of increased efficiency. Were exceptional shocks and competitive pressures responsible for inducing corporate weight-loss campaigns? How could administrative "fat" have accumulated in the first place? That large, successful corporations tend to acquire bloated staffs is a commonplace in popular discourse, and many economists give credence to this behavior when they seek (and find) favorable effects on productivity of management buyouts, "refocusing" of diversified enterprises, the excision of layers of supervisory management, and other reorganizations put forth as means to improve productivity. Yet only with caution does one maintain any hypothesis about productivity shortfall or technical inefficiency, lest one seem ignorant of the Law of Cash-Strewn Footpaths: if cost-efficiency could be improved, somebody would already have profited by improving it. In this paper we investigate the possibility that nonproduction employment in U.S. manufacturing behaves as if fat could be excised by the squeezing. The investigation proceeds through two stages. First, working with disaggregated manufacturing industries observed during 1967-86,

[1]  Andrei Shleifer,et al.  Breach of Trust in Hostile Takeovers , 1987 .

[2]  M. C. Jensen,et al.  The Modern Industrial Revolution, Exit, and the Failure of Internal Control Systems , 1993, A Theory of the Firm.

[3]  F. Caeldries Reengineering the Corporation: A Manifesto for Business Revolution , 1994 .

[4]  S. Wadhwani,et al.  Productivity Growth in UK Companies , 1991 .

[5]  Araújo,et al.  An Evolutionary theory of economic change , 1983 .

[6]  H. Bloch Prices, Costs, and Profits in Canadian Manufacturing: The Influence of Tariffs and Concentration , 1974 .

[7]  Henry S. Farber,et al.  The Incidence and Costs of Job Loss: 1982-1991 , 1993 .

[8]  A. Shleifer,et al.  Hostile Takeovers in the 1980s: The Return to Corporate Specialization , 1990 .

[9]  Nonproduction workers in U.S. manufacturing , 1968 .

[10]  Z. Griliches,et al.  Changes in the Demand for Skilled Labor within U.S. Manufacturing Industries: Evidence from the Annual Survey of Manufacturing , 1993 .

[11]  Ernst R. Berndt,et al.  High-Tech Capital Formation and Labor Composition in U.S. Manufacturing Industries: An Exploratory Analysis , 1992 .

[12]  Thomas A. Pugel Foreign Trade and US Market Performance , 1980 .

[13]  Nancy Weiner,et al.  White collar productivity , 1983 .

[14]  F. Lichtenberg,et al.  The Effect of Ownership Changes on the Employment and Wages of Central Office and Other Personnel , 1990, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[15]  David W. Blackwell,et al.  Plant-closing decisions and the market value of the firm , 1990 .

[16]  F. Scherer,et al.  R&D Reactions To High-Technology Import Competition , 1992 .

[17]  K. Wruck,et al.  Financial distress, reorganization, and organizational efficiency , 1990 .

[18]  Richard E. Caves,et al.  Industrial Efficiency in Six Nations , 1992 .

[19]  James L. Medoff,et al.  Substitution between Production Labor and Other Inputs in Unionized and Nonunionized Manufacturing , 1982 .

[20]  A. Auerbach,et al.  Corporate Takeovers: Causes and Consequences , 1988 .

[21]  R. Caves,et al.  Efficiency in U.S. manufacturing industries , 1990 .

[22]  M. Dertouzos,et al.  Made in America: Regaining the Productive Edge , 1989 .

[23]  R. Glenn Hubbard,et al.  Business Cycles and the Relationship between Concentration and Price-Cost Margins , 1986 .

[24]  M. Kosters Workers and Their Wages: Changing Patterns in the United States , 1995 .

[25]  James A. Brickley,et al.  Internal corporate restructuring: An empirical analysis , 1990 .

[26]  D. Hamermesh,et al.  The Demand for Labor in the Long Run , 1984 .

[27]  W. Niskanen Bureaucracy and representative government , 1971 .

[28]  D. Herz Worker Displacement in a Period of Rapid Job Expansion: 1983-87 , 1990 .

[29]  Bengt Holmstrom,et al.  Moral Hazard in Teams , 1982 .

[30]  M. Shubik,et al.  A Behavioral Theory of the Firm. , 1964 .

[31]  Frederic M. Scherer,et al.  Mergers, sell-offs, and economic efficiency , 1987 .

[32]  G. Constantinides The Disposition to Sell Winners Too Early and Ride Losers Too Long: Theory and Evidence: Discussion , 1985 .

[33]  J. Macdonald DOES IMPORT COMPETITION FORCE EFFICIENT PRODUCTION , 1994 .

[34]  Donald Siegel,et al.  Productivity and Changes in Ownership of Manufactoring Plants , 1987 .

[35]  M. Hammer,et al.  Reengineering the Corporation , 1993 .

[36]  M. Statman,et al.  Project Termination Announcements and the Market Value of the Firm , 1989 .

[37]  Wallace N. Davidson,et al.  Layoff Announcements and Stockholder Wealth , 1991 .

[38]  Stephen Nickell,et al.  Productivity growth in U.K. companies, 1975-1986 , 1992 .

[39]  Paul Geroski,et al.  Entry, innovation and productivity growth , 1989 .

[40]  H. Demsetz,et al.  Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization , 1975, IEEE Engineering Management Review.

[41]  Ana Revenga Exporting Jobs? The Impact of Import Competition on Employment and Wages in U. S. Manufacturing , 1992 .

[42]  Richard S. Ruback,et al.  Does Corporate Performance Improve after Mergers? , 1990 .

[43]  S. Winter,et al.  An evolutionary theory of economic change , 1983 .

[44]  Margaret M. Blair The deal decade : what takeovers and leveraged buyouts mean for corporate governance , 1993 .

[45]  E. Johnsen Richard M. Cyert & James G. March, A Behavioral Theory of The Firm, Prentice-Hall, Inc., Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey, 1963, 332 s. , 1964 .

[46]  Lorin M. Hitt,et al.  Is Information Systems Spending Productive? New Evidence and New Results , 1993, ICIS.